Damodaran Valuation

December 22, 2017 | Author: bharathkumar_asokan | Category: Peg Ratio, Valuation (Finance), Beta (Finance), Price–Earnings Ratio, Book Value
Share Embed Donate


Short Description

Download Damodaran Valuation...

Description

Equity Instruments & Markets: Part II B40.3331 Relative Valuation and Private Company Valuation Aswath Damodaran

Aswath Damodaran

1

The Essence of relative valuation?

 

In relative valuation, the value of an asset is compared to the values assessed by the market for similar or comparable assets. To do relative valuation then, • • •

Aswath Damodaran

we need to identify comparable assets and obtain market values for these assets convert these market values into standardized values, since the absolute prices cannot be compared This process of standardizing creates price multiples. compare the standardized value or multiple for the asset being analyzed to the standardized values for comparable asset, controlling for any differences between the firms that might affect the multiple, to judge whether the asset is under or over valued

2

Relative valuation is pervasive… 

Most valuations on Wall Street are relative valuations. • • •



Almost 85% of equity research reports are based upon a multiple and comparables. More than 50% of all acquisition valuations are based upon multiples Rules of thumb based on multiples are not only common but are often the basis for final valuation judgments.

While there are more discounted cashflow valuations in consulting and corporate finance, they are often relative valuations masquerading as discounted cash flow valuations. • •

Aswath Damodaran

The objective in many discounted cashflow valuations is to back into a number that has been obtained by using a multiple. The terminal value in a significant number of discounted cashflow valuations is estimated using a multiple.

3

Why relative valuation?

“If you think I’m crazy, you should see the guy who lives across the hall” Jerry Seinfeld talking about Kramer in a Seinfeld episode

“ A little inaccuracy sometimes saves tons of explanation” H.H. Munro

“ If you are going to screw up, make sure that you have lots of company” Ex-portfolio manager Aswath Damodaran

4

So, you believe only in intrinsic value? Here’s why you should still care about relative value 

 

Even if you are a true believer in discounted cashflow valuation, presenting your findings on a relative valuation basis will make it more likely that your findings/recommendations will reach a receptive audience. In some cases, relative valuation can help find weak spots in discounted cash flow valuations and fix them. The problem with multiples is not in their use but in their abuse. If we can find ways to frame multiples right, we should be able to use them better.

Aswath Damodaran

5

Multiples are just standardized estimates of price…

 

You can standardize either the equity value of an asset or the value of the asset itself, which goes in the numerator. You can standardize by dividing by the •

Earnings of the asset – – – –



Price/Earnings Ratio (PE) and variants (PEG and Relative PE) Value/EBIT Value/EBITDA Value/Cash Flow

Book value of the asset – Price/Book Value(of Equity) (PBV) – Value/ Book Value of Assets – Value/Replacement Cost (Tobin’s Q)



Revenues generated by the asset – Price/Sales per Share (PS) – Value/Sales



Aswath Damodaran

Asset or Industry Specific Variable (Price/kwh, Price per ton of steel ....)

6

The Four Steps to Understanding Multiples



Define the multiple •



Describe the multiple •



Too many people who use a multiple have no idea what its cross sectional distribution is. If you do not know what the cross sectional distribution of a multiple is, it is difficult to look at a number and pass judgment on whether it is too high or low.

Analyze the multiple •



In use, the same multiple can be defined in different ways by different users. When comparing and using multiples, estimated by someone else, it is critical that we understand how the multiples have been estimated

It is critical that we understand the fundamentals that drive each multiple, and the nature of the relationship between the multiple and each variable.

Apply the multiple •

Aswath Damodaran

Defining the comparable universe and controlling for differences is far more difficult in practice than it is in theory.

7

Definitional Tests



Is the multiple consistently defined? •



Proposition 1: Both the value (the numerator) and the standardizing variable ( the denominator) should be to the same claimholders in the firm. In other words, the value of equity should be divided by equity earnings or equity book value, and firm value should be divided by firm earnings or book value.

Is the multiple uniformly estimated? • •

Aswath Damodaran

The variables used in defining the multiple should be estimated uniformly across assets in the “comparable firm” list. If earnings-based multiples are used, the accounting rules to measure earnings should be applied consistently across assets. The same rule applies with bookvalue based multiples.

8

Descriptive Tests

 

What is the average and standard deviation for this multiple, across the universe (market)? What is the median for this multiple? •



How large are the outliers to the distribution, and how do we deal with the outliers? •

 

The median for this multiple is often a more reliable comparison point.

Throwing out the outliers may seem like an obvious solution, but if the outliers all lie on one side of the distribution (they usually are large positive numbers), this can lead to a biased estimate.

Are there cases where the multiple cannot be estimated? Will ignoring these cases lead to a biased estimate of the multiple? How has this multiple changed over time?

Aswath Damodaran

9

Analytical Tests



What are the fundamentals that determine and drive these multiples? • •



Proposition 2: Embedded in every multiple are all of the variables that drive every discounted cash flow valuation - growth, risk and cash flow patterns. In fact, using a simple discounted cash flow model and basic algebra should yield the fundamentals that drive a multiple

How do changes in these fundamentals change the multiple? •



Aswath Damodaran

The relationship between a fundamental (like growth) and a multiple (such as PE) is seldom linear. For example, if firm A has twice the growth rate of firm B, it will generally not trade at twice its PE ratio Proposition 3: It is impossible to properly compare firms on a multiple, if we do not know the nature of the relationship between fundamentals and the multiple.

10

Application Tests



Given the firm that we are valuing, what is a “comparable” firm? •





While traditional analysis is built on the premise that firms in the same sector are comparable firms, valuation theory would suggest that a comparable firm is one which is similar to the one being analyzed in terms of fundamentals. Proposition 4: There is no reason why a firm cannot be compared with another firm in a very different business, if the two firms have the same risk, growth and cash flow characteristics.

Given the comparable firms, how do we adjust for differences across firms on the fundamentals? •

Aswath Damodaran

Proposition 5: It is impossible to find an exactly identical firm to the one you are valuing.

11

Price Earnings Ratio: Definition

PE = Market Price per Share / Earnings per Share 



There are a number of variants on the basic PE ratio in use. They are based upon how the price and the earnings are defined. Price: •

is usually the current price (though some like to use average price over last 6 months or year)

EPS: •

• • •

Aswath Damodaran

Time variants: EPS in most recent financial year (current), EPS in most recent four quarters (trailing), EPS expected in next fiscal year or next four quartes (both called forward) or EPS in some future year Primary, diluted or partially diluted Before or after extraordinary items Measured using different accounting rules (options expensed or not, pension fund income counted or not…)

12

PE Ratio: Distribution for the US: January 2004

Aswath Damodaran

13

PE: Deciphering the Distribution

Mean Standard Error Median Kurtosis Skewness Minimum Maximum Count 500th largest 500th smallest

Aswath Damodaran

Current PE 41.41 2.42 20.76 1062.81 27.78 0.40 6841.25 4032 54.50 11.31

Trailing PE Forward PE 41.53 30.90 3.64 1.10 19.39 19.21 700.63 252.62 24.21 12.48 1.22 2.57 7184.00 1430.00 3492 2281 43.98 31.13 11.13 14.29

14

Comparing PE Ratios: US, Europe, Japan and Emerging Markets Median PE Japan = 24.74 US = 20.76 Em. Mkts = 18.87 Europe = 15.99

Aswath Damodaran

15

PE Ratio: Understanding the Fundamentals

 

To understand the fundamentals, start with a basic equity discounted cash flow model. With the dividend discount model, P0 =





DPS1 r ! gn

Dividing both sides by the current earnings per share, P0 Payout Ratio * (1 + g n ) = PE = EPS0 r-gn

If this had been a FCFE Model,

P0 =

FCFE1 r ! gn

P0 (FCFE/Earnings) * (1+ g n ) = PE = EPS0 r-g n Aswath Damodaran

16

!

PE Ratio and Fundamentals

  



Proposition: Other things held equal, higher growth firms will have higher PE ratios than lower growth firms. Proposition: Other things held equal, higher risk firms will have lower PE ratios than lower risk firms Proposition: Other things held equal, firms with lower reinvestment needs will have higher PE ratios than firms with higher reinvestment rates. Of course, other things are difficult to hold equal since high growth firms, tend to have risk and high reinvestment rats.

Aswath Damodaran

17

Using the Fundamental Model to Estimate PE For a High Growth Firm



The price-earnings ratio for a high growth firm can also be related to fundamentals. In the special case of the two-stage dividend discount model, this relationship can be made explicit fairly simply: P0 =

• 

" (1+ g)n % EPS0 * Payout Ratio *(1+ g)* $1 ! # (1+ r) n & r-g

+

EPS0 * Payout Ratio n *(1+ g)n *(1+ g n ) (r -g n )(1+ r)n

For a firm that does not pay what it can afford to in dividends, substitute FCFE/Earnings for the payout ratio.

Dividing both sides by the earnings per share: " (1 + g)n % ' Payout Ratio * (1 + g) * $ 1 ! # (1+ r) n & P0 Payout Ratio n *(1+ g) n * (1 + gn ) = + EPS0 r -g (r - g n )(1+ r) n

Aswath Damodaran

18

Expanding the Model



 

In this model, the PE ratio for a high growth firm is a function of growth, risk and payout, exactly the same variables that it was a function of for the stable growth firm. The only difference is that these inputs have to be estimated for two phases the high growth phase and the stable growth phase. Expanding to more than two phases, say the three stage model, will mean that risk, growth and cash flow patterns in each stage.

Aswath Damodaran

19

A Simple Example

Assume that you have been asked to estimate the PE ratio for a firm which has the following characteristics: Variable High Growth Phase Stable Growth Phase Expected Growth Rate 25% 8% Payout Ratio 20% 50% Beta 1.00 1.00 Number of years 5 years Forever after year 5  Riskfree rate = T.Bond Rate = 6%  Required rate of return = 6% + 1(5.5%)= 11.5% 

# (1.25) 5 & 0.2 * (1.25) * %1" 5( 5 $ (1.115) ' 0.5 * (1.25) * (1.08) PE = + = 28.75 (.115 - .25) (.115 - .08) (1.115) 5

!

Aswath Damodaran

20

PE and Growth: Firm grows at x% for 5 years, 8% thereafter

PE Ratios and Expected Growth: Interest Rate Scenarios 180

160

140

PE Ratio

120

r=4% r=6% r=8% r=10%

100

80

60

40

20

0 5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

50%

Expected Growth Rate

Aswath Damodaran

21

PE Ratios and Length of High Growth: 25% growth for n years; 8% thereafter

Aswath Damodaran

22

PE and Risk: Effects of Changing Betas on PE Ratio: Firm with x% growth for 5 years; 8% thereafter

PE Ratios and Beta: Growth Scenarios 50 45 40 35

g=25% g=20% g=15% g=8%

25

PE

Ratio

30

20 15 10 5 0 0.75

1.00

1.25

1.50

1.75

2.00

Beta

Aswath Damodaran

23

PE and Payout

Aswath Damodaran

24

I. Assessing Emerging Market PE Ratios - Early 2000 PE: Emerging Markets 35

30

25

20

15

10

5

0 Mexico

Aswath Damodaran

Malaysia

Singapore

Taiwan

Hong Kong

Venezuela

Brazil

Argentina

Chile

25

Comparisons across countries



  

In July 2000, a market strategist is making the argument that Brazil and Venezuela are cheap relative to Chile, because they have much lower PE ratios. Would you agree? Yes No What are some of the factors that may cause one market’s PE ratios to be lower than another market’s PE?

Aswath Damodaran

26

II. A Comparison across countries: June 2000

Country UK Germany France Switzerland Belgium Italy Sweden Netherlands Australia Japan US Canada

Aswath Damodaran

PE 22.02 26.33 29.04 19.6 14.74 28.23 32.39 21.1 21.69 52.25 25.14 26.14

Dividend Yield 2-yr rate 2.59% 5.93% 1.88% 5.06% 1.34% 5.11% 1.42% 3.62% 2.66% 5.15% 1.76% 5.27% 1.11% 4.67% 2.07% 5.10% 3.12% 6.29% 0.71% 0.58% 1.10% 6.05% 0.99% 5.70%

10-yr rate 5.85% 5.32% 5.48% 3.83% 5.70% 5.70% 5.26% 5.47% 6.25% 1.85% 5.85% 5.77%

10yr - 2yr -0.08% 0.26% 0.37% 0.21% 0.55% 0.43% 0.59% 0.37% -0.04% 1.27% -0.20% 0.07%

27

Correlations and Regression of PE Ratios



Correlations • •



Correlation between PE ratio and long term interest rates = -0.733 Correlation between PE ratio and yield spread = 0.706

Regression Results PE Ratio = 42.62 - 3.61 (10’yr rate) + 8.47 (10-yr - 2 yr rate) R2 = 59% Input the interest rates as percent. For instance, the predicted PE ratio for Japan with this regression would be: PE: Japan = 42.62 - 3.61 (1.85) + 8.47 (1.27) = 46.70 At an actual PE ratio of 52.25, Japanese stocks are slightly overvalued.

Aswath Damodaran

28

Predicted PE Ratios

Country Actual PE Predicted PE Under or Over Valued UK 22.02 20.83 5.71% Germany 26.33 25.62 2.76% France 29.04 25.98 11.80% Switzerland 19.6 30.58 -35.90% Belgium 14.74 26.71 -44.81% Italy 28.23 25.69 9.89% Sweden 32.39 28.63 13.12% Netherlands 21.1 26.01 -18.88% Australia 21.69 19.73 9.96% Japan 52.25 46.70 11.89% United States 25.14 19.81 26.88% Canada 26.14 22.39 16.75% Aswath Damodaran

29

III. An Example with Emerging Markets: June 2000

Aswath Damodaran

Country

PE Ratio

Argentina Brazil Chile Hong Kong India Indonesia Malaysia Mexico Pakistan Peru Phillipines Singapore South Korea Thailand Turkey Venezuela

14 21 25 20 17 15 14 19 14 15 15 24 21 21 12 20

Interest Rates 18.00% 14.00% 9.50% 8.00% 11.48% 21.00% 5.67% 11.50% 19.00% 18.00% 17.00% 6.50% 10.00% 12.75% 25.00% 15.00%

GDP Real Growth 2.50% 4.80% 5.50% 6.00% 4.20% 4.00% 3.00% 5.50% 3.00% 4.90% 3.80% 5.20% 4.80% 5.50% 2.00% 3.50%

Country Risk 45 35 15 15 25 50 40 30 45 50 45 5 25 25 35 45

30

Regression Results



The regression of PE ratios on these variables provides the following – PE = 16.16

- 7.94 Interest Rates + 154.40 Growth in GDP - 0.1116 Country Risk R Squared = 73%

Aswath Damodaran

31

Predicted PE Ratios

Aswath Damodaran

Country

PE Ratio

Argentina Brazil Chile Hong Kong India Indonesia Malaysia Mexico Pakistan Peru Phillipines Singapore South Korea Thailand Turkey Venezuela

14 21 25 20 17 15 14 19 14 15 15 24 21 21 12 20

Interest Rates 18.00% 14.00% 9.50% 8.00% 11.48% 21.00% 5.67% 11.50% 19.00% 18.00% 17.00% 6.50% 10.00% 12.75% 25.00% 15.00%

GDP Real Growth 2.50% 4.80% 5.50% 6.00% 4.20% 4.00% 3.00% 5.50% 3.00% 4.90% 3.80% 5.20% 4.80% 5.50% 2.00% 3.50%

Country Risk 45 35 15 15 25 50 40 30 45 50 45 5 25 25 35 45

Predicted PE 13.57 18.55 22.22 23.11 18.94 15.09 15.87 20.39 14.26 16.71 15.65 23.11 19.98 20.85 13.35 15.35

32

IV. Comparisons of PE across time: PE Ratio for the S&P 500

Aswath Damodaran

33

Is low (high) PE cheap (expensive)?



A market strategist argues that stocks are over priced because the PE ratio today is too high relative to the average PE ratio across time. Do you agree?  Yes  No



If you do not agree, what factors might explain the higher PE ratio today?

Aswath Damodaran

34

E/P Ratios , T.Bond Rates and Term Structure

Aswath Damodaran

35

Regression Results

  

There is a strong positive relationship between E/P ratios and T.Bond rates, as evidenced by the correlation of 0.69 between the two variables., In addition, there is evidence that the term structure also affects the PE ratio. In the following regression, using 1960-2003 data, we regress E/P ratios against the level of T.Bond rates and a term structure variable (T.Bond T.Bill rate) E/P = 2.03% + 0.753 T.Bond Rate - 0.355 (T.Bond Rate-T.Bill Rate) (2.19) (6.38) (-1.38) R squared = 50.85%

Aswath Damodaran

36

Estimate the E/P Ratio Today

   

T. Bond Rate = T.Bond Rate - T.Bill Rate = Expected E/P Ratio = Expected PE Ratio =

Aswath Damodaran

37

V. Comparing PE ratios across firms

Company Name Coca-Cola Bottling Molson Inc. Ltd. 'A' Anheuser -Busch Cor by Distiller ies Ltd. Chalone Wine Gr oup Ltd. Andr es Wines Ltd. 'A' Todhunter Int'l Br own-For man 'B' Coor s (Adolph) 'B' PepsiCo, Inc. Coca-Cola Boston Beer 'A' Whitman Cor p. Mondavi (Rober t) 'A' Coca-Cola Enter pr ises

Tr ailing PE 29.18 43.65 24.31 16.24 21.76 8.96 8.94 10.07 23.02 33.00 44.33 10.59 25.19 16.47 37.14

Expected Gr owth 9.50% 15.50% 11.00% 7.50% 14.00% 3.50% 3.00% 11.50% 10.00% 10.50% 19.00% 17.13% 11.50% 14.00% 27.00%

Standar d Dev 20.58% 21.88% 22.92% 23.66% 24.08% 24.70% 25.74% 29.43% 29.52% 31.35% 35.51% 39.58% 44.26% 45.84% 51.34%

Hansen Natur al Cor p

9.70

17.00%

62.45%

Aswath Damodaran

38

A Question

You are reading an equity research report on this sector, and the analyst claims that Andres Wine and Hansen Natural are under valued because they have low PE ratios. Would you agree?  Yes  No  Why or why not?

Aswath Damodaran

39

VI. Comparing PE Ratios across a Sector Company Name PT Indosat ADR Telebras ADR Telecom Corporation of New Zealand ADR Telecom Argentina Stet - France Telecom SA ADR B Hellenic Telecommunication Organization SA ADR Telecomunicaciones de Chile ADR Swisscom AG ADR Asia Satellite Telecom Holdings ADR Portugal Telecom SA ADR Telefonos de Mexico ADR L Matav RT ADR Telstra ADR Gilat Communications Deutsche Telekom AG ADR British Telecommunications PLC ADR Tele Danmark AS ADR Telekomunikasi Indonesia ADR Cable & Wireless PLC ADR APT Satellite Holdings ADR Telefonica SA ADR Royal KPN NV ADR Telecom Italia SPA ADR Nippon Telegraph & Telephone ADR France Telecom SA ADR Korea Telecom ADR

Aswath Damodaran

PE 7.8 8.9 11.2 12.5 12.8 16.6 18.3 19.6 20.8 21.1 21.5 21.7 22.7 24.6 25.7 27 28.4 29.8 31 32.5 35.7 42.2 44.3 45.2 71.3

Growth 0.06 0.075 0.11 0.08 0.12 0.08 0.11 0.16 0.13 0.14 0.22 0.12 0.31 0.11 0.07 0.09 0.32 0.14 0.33 0.18 0.13 0.14 0.2 0.19 0.44

40

PE, Growth and Risk Dependent variable is: R squared = 66.2%

PE

R squared (adjusted) = 63.1%

Variable Coefficient SE Constant 13.1151 3.471 Growth rate 1.21223 19.27 Emerging Market -13.8531 3.606 Emerging Market is a dummy: 1 if emerging market 0 if not

Aswath Damodaran

t-ratio 3.78 6.29 -3.84

prob 0.0010 ≤ 0.0001 0.0009

41

Is Telebras under valued?  

Predicted PE = 13.12 + 1.2122 (7.5) - 13.85 (1) = 8.35 At an actual price to earnings ratio of 8.9, Telebras is slightly overvalued.

Aswath Damodaran

42

Using comparable firms- Pros and Cons



The most common approach to estimating the PE ratio for a firm is • • •



to choose a group of comparable firms, to calculate the average PE ratio for this group and to subjectively adjust this average for differences between the firm being valued and the comparable firms.

Problems with this approach. • •

• •

Aswath Damodaran

The definition of a 'comparable' firm is essentially a subjective one. The use of other firms in the industry as the control group is often not a solution because firms within the same industry can have very different business mixes and risk and growth profiles. There is also plenty of potential for bias. Even when a legitimate group of comparable firms can be constructed, differences will continue to persist in fundamentals between the firm being valued and this group.

43

Using the entire crosssection: A regression approach

 

In contrast to the 'comparable firm' approach, the information in the entire cross-section of firms can be used to predict PE ratios. The simplest way of summarizing this information is with a multiple regression, with the PE ratio as the dependent variable, and proxies for risk, growth and payout forming the independent variables.

Aswath Damodaran

44

PE versus Growth Current PE vs Expected Growth in EPS January 2004: US Companies 1 20

1 00

80

60

Current PE

40

20 0 -20

0

20

40

60

80

Expected Growth in E PS: next 5 y ears

Aswath Damodaran

45

PE Ratio: Standard Regression for US stocks - January 2004 Mod el Summary Mode l 1

R .467 a

R Square .21 8

Adjusted R Square .217

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 1049.7506205 340

a. Predictor s: ( Constant), PAYOUT, Regre ssion Be ta , Expected Gr owth in EPS: next 5 years

Co effici entsa,b Unstandardized Coefficients Mode l 1

B (Constant) Expected G rowth in EPS: next 5 years Regr ession B eta PAYOUT

Std. Error

9.475

.96 1

.814

.04 6

6.283 6.E-02

Standar dized Coefficients Beta

t

Sig.

9.862

.000

.375

17.55 8

.000

.43 7

.298

14.37 5

.000

.01 4

.092

4.161

.000

a. Dependent Va riable: Current PE b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighted by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran

46

Problems with the regression methodology

 



The basic regression assumes a linear relationship between PE ratios and the financial proxies, and that might not be appropriate. The basic relationship between PE ratios and financial variables itself might not be stable, and if it shifts from year to year, the predictions from the model may not be reliable. The independent variables are correlated with each other. For example, high growth firms tend to have high risk. This multi-collinearity makes the coefficients of the regressions unreliable and may explain the large changes in these coefficients from period to period.

Aswath Damodaran

47

The Multicollinearity Problem Correlatio ns

Expected G rowth in Reven ues: next 5 year s

Pear son Correlation

PAYOUT

Regr ession Beta .031

.

.228

.000 1185

Sig. (2 -tailed) N

Regression Bet a

Expected Growth in Revenues: next 5 ye ars 1

PAYOUT -.325**

147 2

1472

Pear son Correlation

.03 1

1

-.183**

Sig. (2 -tailed)

.22 8

.

.000

N

147 2

6933

4187

Pear son Correlation

-.325**

-.183**

1

.00 0

.000

.

118 5

4187

4187

Sig. (2 -tailed) N

**. Correlation is significa nt at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).

Aswath Damodaran

48

Using the PE ratio regression 

Assume that you were given the following information for Dell. The firm has an expected growth rate of 10%, a beta of 1.20 and pays no dividends. Based upon the regression, estimate the predicted PE ratio for Dell. Predicted PE =



Dell is actually trading at 22 times earnings. What does the predicted PE tell you?

Aswath Damodaran

49

The value of growth Time Period Value of extra 1% of growth January 2004 0.812 July 2003 1.228 January 2003 2.621 July 2002 0.859 January 2002 1.003 July 2001 1.251 January 2001 1.457 July 2000 1.761 January 2000 2.105 The value of growth is in terms of additional PE…

Aswath Damodaran

Equity Risk Premium 3.69% 3.88% 4.10% 4.35% 3.62% 3.05% 2.75% 2.20% 2.05%

50

Investment Strategies that compare PE to the expected growth rate





If we assume that all firms within a sector have similar growth rates and risk, a strategy of picking the lowest PE ratio stock in each sector will yield undervalued stocks. Portfolio managers and analysts sometimes compare PE ratios to the expected growth rate to identify under and overvalued stocks. • •

Aswath Damodaran

In the simplest form of this approach, firms with PE ratios less than their expected growth rate are viewed as undervalued. In its more general form, the ratio of PE ratio to growth is used as a measure of relative value.

51

Problems with comparing PE ratios to expected growth

  

In its simple form, there is no basis for believing that a firm is undervalued just because it has a PE ratio less than expected growth. This relationship may be consistent with a fairly valued or even an overvalued firm, if interest rates are high, or if a firm is high risk. As interest rate decrease (increase), fewer (more) stocks will emerge as undervalued using this approach.

Aswath Damodaran

52

PE Ratio versus Growth - The Effect of Interest rates: Average Risk firm with 25% growth for 5 years; 8% thereafter

Aswath Damodaran

53

PE Ratios Less Than The Expected Growth Rate



In January 2004, • •



33% of firms had PE ratios lower than the expected 5-year growth rate 67% of firms had PE ratios higher than the expected 5-year growth rate

In comparison, • •

Aswath Damodaran

38.1% of firms had PE ratios less than the expected 5-year growth rate in September 1991 65.3% of firm had PE ratios less than the expected 5-year growth rate in 1981.

54

PEG Ratio: Definition





The PEG ratio is the ratio of price earnings to expected growth in earnings per share. PEG = PE / Expected Growth Rate in Earnings Definitional tests: •

Is the growth rate used to compute the PEG ratio – on the same base? (base year EPS) – over the same period?(2 years, 5 years) – from the same source? (analyst projections, consensus estimates..)



Is the earnings used to compute the PE ratio consistent with the growth rate estimate? – No double counting: If the estimate of growth in earnings per share is from the current year, it would be a mistake to use forward EPS in computing PE – If looking at foreign stocks or ADRs, is the earnings used for the PE ratio consistent with the growth rate estimate? (US analysts use the ADR EPS)

Aswath Damodaran

55

PEG Ratio: Distribution

Aswath Damodaran

56

PEG Ratios: The Beverage Sector Company Name Coca-Cola Bottling Molson Inc. Ltd. 'A' Anheuser -Busch Cor by Distiller ies Ltd. Chalone Wine Gr oup Ltd. Andr es Wines Ltd. 'A' Todhunter Int'l Br own-For man 'B' Coor s (Adolph) 'B' PepsiCo, Inc. Coca-Cola Boston Beer 'A' Whitman Cor p. Mondavi (Rober t) 'A' Coca-Cola Enter pr ises Hansen Natur al Cor p Aver age

Aswath Damodaran

Tr ailing PE 29.18 43.65 24.31 16.24 21.76 14.00% 8.96 8.94 10.07 23.02 33.00 44.33 10.59 25.19 16.47 37.14 9.70 22.66

Gr owth 9.50% 15.50% 11.00% 7.50% 24.08% 3.50% 3.00% 11.50% 10.00% 10.50% 19.00% 17.13% 11.50% 14.00% 27.00% 17.00%

Std Dev 20.58% 21.88% 22.92% 23.66% 1.55 24.70% 25.74% 29.43% 29.52% 31.35% 35.51% 39.58% 44.26% 45.84% 51.34% 62.45%

P EG 3.07 2.82 2.21 2.16

0.13

0.33

2.00

2.56 2.98 0.88 2.30 3.14 2.33 0.62 2.19 1.18 1.38 0.57

57

PEG Ratio: Reading the Numbers



  

The average PEG ratio for the beverage sector is 2.00. The lowest PEG ratio in the group belongs to Hansen Natural, which has a PEG ratio of 0.57. Using this measure of value, Hansen Natural is the most under valued stock in the group the most over valued stock in the group What other explanation could there be for Hansen’s low PEG ratio?

Aswath Damodaran

58

PEG Ratio: Analysis



To understand the fundamentals that determine PEG ratios, let us return again to a 2-stage equity discounted cash flow model P0 =



" (1+ g)n % EPS0 * Payout Ratio *(1+ g)* $1 ! # (1+ r) n & r-g

+

EPS0 * Payout Ratio n *(1+ g)n *(1+ g n ) (r -g n )(1+ r)n

Dividing both sides of the equation by the earnings gives us the equation for the PE ratio. Dividing it again by the expected growth ‘g’ " (1+ g)n % Payout Ratio *(1 + g) * $ 1 ! # (1 + r) n & Payout Ratio n * (1+ g)n * (1+ g n ) PEG = + g(r - g) g(r - gn )(1 + r)n

Aswath Damodaran

59

PEG Ratios and Fundamentals



Risk and payout, which affect PE ratios, continue to affect PEG ratios as well. •



Implication: When comparing PEG ratios across companies, we are making implicit or explicit assumptions about these variables.

Dividing PE by expected growth does not neutralize the effects of expected growth, since the relationship between growth and value is not linear and fairly complex (even in a 2-stage model)

Aswath Damodaran

60

A Simple Example

Assume that you have been asked to estimate the PEG ratio for a firm which has the following characteristics: Variable High Growth Phase Stable Growth Phase Expected Growth Rate 25% 8% Payout Ratio 20% 50% Beta 1.00 1.00  Riskfree rate = T.Bond Rate = 6%  Required rate of return = 6% + 1(5.5%)= 11.5%  The PEG ratio for this firm can be estimated as follows: 

# (1.25) 5 & 0.2 * (1.25) * %1" 5( 0.5 * (1.25) 5 * (1.08) $ (1.115) ' PEG = + = 115 or 1.15 .25(.115 - .25) .25(.115 - .08) (1.115) 5

Aswath Damodaran

!

61

PEG Ratios and Risk

Aswath Damodaran

62

PEG Ratios and Quality of Growth

Aswath Damodaran

63

PE Ratios and Expected Growth

Aswath Damodaran

64

PEG Ratios and Fundamentals: Propositions



Proposition 1: High risk companies will trade at much lower PEG ratios than low risk companies with the same expected growth rate. •



Proposition 2: Companies that can attain growth more efficiently by investing less in better return projects will have higher PEG ratios than companies that grow at the same rate less efficiently. •



Corollary 1: The company that looks most under valued on a PEG ratio basis in a sector may be the riskiest firm in the sector

Corollary 2: Companies that look cheap on a PEG ratio basis may be companies with high reinvestment rates and poor project returns.

Proposition 3: Companies with very low or very high growth rates will tend to have higher PEG ratios than firms with average growth rates. This bias is worse for low growth stocks. •

Aswath Damodaran

Corollary 3: PEG ratios do not neutralize the growth effect.

65

PE, PEG Ratios and Risk 45

2.5

40 2

35 30

1.5 25

PE PEG Ratio

20 1 15 10

0.5

5 0

0 Lowest

Aswath Damodaran

2

3

4

Highest

66

PEG Ratio: Returning to the Beverage Sector Company Name Coca-Cola Bottling Molson Inc. Ltd. 'A' Anheuser -Busch Cor by Distiller ies Ltd. Chalone Wine Gr oup Ltd. Andr es Wines Ltd. 'A' Todhunter Int'l Br own-For man 'B' Coor s (Adolph) 'B' PepsiCo, Inc. Coca-Cola Boston Beer 'A' Whitman Cor p. Mondavi (Rober t) 'A' Coca-Cola Enter pr ises Hansen Natur al Cor p

Tr ailing PE 29.18 43.65 24.31 16.24 21.76 8.96 8.94 10.07 23.02 33.00 44.33 10.59 25.19 16.47 37.14 9.70

Gr owth 9.50% 15.50% 11.00% 7.50% 14.00% 3.50% 3.00% 11.50% 10.00% 10.50% 19.00% 17.13% 11.50% 14.00% 27.00% 17.00%

Std Dev 20.58% 21.88% 22.92% 23.66% 24.08% 24.70% 25.74% 29.43% 29.52% 31.35% 35.51% 39.58% 44.26% 45.84% 51.34% 62.45%

P EG 3.07 2.82 2.21 2.16 1.55 2.56 2.98 0.88 2.30 3.14 2.33 0.62 2.19 1.18 1.38 0.57

Aver age

22.66

0.13

0.33

2.00

Aswath Damodaran

67

Analyzing PE/Growth

Given that the PEG ratio is still determined by the expected growth rates, risk and cash flow patterns, it is necessary that we control for differences in these variables.  Regressing PEG against risk and a measure of the growth dispersion, we get: PEG = 3.61 -.0286 (Expected Growth) - .0375 (Std Deviation in Prices) R Squared = 44.75%  In other words, 

• • 

PEG ratios will be lower for high growth companies PEG ratios will be lower for high risk companies

We also ran the regression using the deviation of the actual growth rate from the industry-average growth rate as the independent variable, with mixed results.

Aswath Damodaran

68

Estimating the PEG Ratio for Hansen



Applying this regression to Hansen, the predicted PEG ratio for the firm can be estimated using Hansen’s measures for the independent variables: • •

Expected Growth Rate = 17.00% Standard Deviation in Stock Prices = 62.45%

Plugging in, Expected PEG Ratio for Hansen = 3.61 - .0286 (17) - .0375 (62.45) = 0.78  With its actual PEG ratio of 0.57, Hansen looks undervalued, notwithstanding its high risk. 

Aswath Damodaran

69

Extending the Comparables





This analysis, which is restricted to firms in the software sector, can be expanded to include all firms in the firm, as long as we control for differences in risk, growth and payout. To look at the cross sectional relationship, we first plotted PEG ratios against expected growth rates.

Aswath Damodaran

70

PEG versus Growth PEG Ratio v s Expected Growth in EPS January 2004: US Companies 10

8

6

PEG Ratio

4

2

0 -20

0

20

40

60

80

1 00

Expected Growth in E PS: next 5 y ears

Aswath Damodaran

71

Analyzing the Relationship 



The relationship in not linear. In fact, the smallest firms seem to have the highest PEG ratios and PEG ratios become relatively stable at higher growth rates. To make the relationship more linear, we converted the expected growth rates in ln(expected growth rate). The relationship between PEG ratios and ln(expected growth rate) was then plotted.

Aswath Damodaran

72

PEG versus ln(Expected Growth) PEG vs ln (Expected Growth) January 2004: US Companies 10

8

6

PEG Ratio

4

2

0 0

1

2

3

4

5

ln (Exp ected Gro wth R ate)

Aswath Damodaran

73

PEG Ratio Regression - US stocks in January 2004 Model Summary Mode l 1

R R Square a .492 .242

Adjusted R Squar e .241

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 91. 242648963259

a. Predictors: ( Constant), LNGROWTH, Re gression B eta, PAYOUT

Co ef fici entsa,b Unstandard ized Coefficients Mode l 1

B 4.308

Std. Er ror .15 5

.539

.03 8

PAYOUT

6.E-03

LNGROWTH

-1.042

(Constant) Regr ession B eta

Standar dized Coefficients Beta

t 27. 774

Sig. .000

.293

14. 249

.000

.00 1

.116

5.262

.000

.05 5

-.404

-18.86

.000

a. Dependent Va riable: PE G Ratio b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran

74

Applying the PEG ratio regression 

Consider Dell again. The stock has an expected growth rate of 10%, a beta of 1.20 and pays out no dividends. What should its PEG ratio be?



If the stock’s actual PE ratio is 23, what does this analysis tell you about the stock?

Aswath Damodaran

75

A Variant on PEG Ratio: The PEGY ratio 



The PEG ratio is biased against low growth firms because the relationship between value and growth is non-linear. One variant that has been devised to consolidate the growth rate and the expected dividend yield: PEGY = PE / (Expected Growth Rate + Dividend Yield) As an example, Con Ed has a PE ratio of 16, an expected growth rate of 5% in earnings and a dividend yield of 4.5%. • •

Aswath Damodaran

PEG = 16/ 5 = 3.2 PEGY = 16/(5+4.5) = 1.7

76

Relative PE: Definition









The relative PE ratio of a firm is the ratio of the PE of the firm to the PE of the market. Relative PE = PE of Firm / PE of Market While the PE can be defined in terms of current earnings, trailing earnings or forward earnings, consistency requires that it be estimated using the same measure of earnings for both the firm and the market. Relative PE ratios are usually compared over time. Thus, a firm or sector which has historically traded at half the market PE (Relative PE = 0.5) is considered over valued if it is trading at a relative PE of 0.7. Relative PE ratios are also used when comparing companies across markets with different PE ratios (Japanese versus US stocks, for example).

Aswath Damodaran

77

Relative PE: Determinants



To analyze the determinants of the relative PE ratios, let us revisit the discounted cash flow model we developed for the PE ratio. Using the 2-stage DDM model as our basis (replacing the payout ratio with the FCFE/Earnings Ratio, if necessary), we get

" (1+ g j )n % ' Payout Ratio j *(1 + g j ) * $ 1 ! (1+ rj )n & # Payout Ratio j,n *(1 + g j )n *(1 + g j,n ) + rj - g j (rj - g j,n )(1 + rj )n Relative PE j = "$ (1+ g m ) n %' Payout Ratio m * (1+ g m )* 1 ! # (1+ rm )n & Payout Ratio m,n * (1+ g m )n *(1 + gm, n ) + n r g (r g )(1+ r ) m m m m,n m where Payout , g , r = Payout, growth and risk of the firm j

j

j

Payoutm, gm, rm = Payout, growth and risk of the market

Aswath Damodaran

78

Relative PE: A Simple Example

Consider the following example of a firm growing at twice the rate as the market, while having the same growth and risk characteristics of the market: Firm Market Expected growth rate 20% 10% Length of Growth Period 5 years 5 years Payout Ratio: first 5 yrs 30% 30% Growth Rate after yr 5 6% 6% Payout Ratio after yr 5 50% 50% Beta 1.00 1.00 Riskfree Rate = 6% 

Aswath Damodaran

79

Estimating Relative PE



The relative PE ratio for this firm can be estimated in two steps. First, we compute the PE ratio for the firm and the market separately: PE firm

PE market



5 " (1.20) % 0.3 * (1.20) * $ 1! # (1.115) 5 & 0.5 * (1.20)5 * (1.06) = + = 15.79 (.115 - .20) (.115 -.06) (1.115)5

" (1.10)5 % 0.3 * (1.10) * $ 1! # (1.115)5 & 0.5 * (1.10) 5 *(1.06) = + = 10.45 5 (.115 - .10) (.115-.06) (1.115)

Relative PE Ratio = 15.79/10.45 = 1.51

Aswath Damodaran

80

Relative PE and Relative Growth

Aswath Damodaran

81

Relative PE: Another Example

In this example, consider a firm with twice the risk as the market, while having the same growth and payout characteristics as the firm: Firm Market Expected growth rate 10% 10% Length of Growth Period 5 years 5 years Payout Ratio: first 5 yrs 30% 30% Growth Rate after yr 5 6% 6% Payout Ratio after yr 5 50% 50% Beta in first 5 years 2.00 1.00 Beta after year 5 1.00 1.00 Riskfree Rate = 6% 

Aswath Damodaran

82

Estimating Relative PE



The relative PE ratio for this firm can be estimated in two steps. First, we compute the PE ratio for the firm and the market separately: PE firm

PE market



" (1.10) 5 % 0.3 * (1.10) * $ 1 ! 5 # (1.17) 5 & 0.5 * (1.10) * (1.06) = + = 8.33 (.17 - .10) (.115- .06) (1.17)5

" (1.10)5 % 0.3 * (1.10) * $ 1! # (1.115)5 & 0.5 * (1.10) 5 *(1.06) = + = 10.45 5 (.115 - .10) (.115-.06) (1.115)

Relative PE Ratio = 8.33/10.45 = 0.80

Aswath Damodaran

83

Relative PE and Relative Risk

Relative PE and Relative Risk: Stable Beta Scenarios 4.5

4

3.5

3

2.5 Beta stays at current level Beta drops to 1 in stable phase 2

1.5

1

0.5

0 0.25

Aswath Damodaran

0.5

0.75

1

1.25

1.5

1.75

2

84

Relative PE: Summary of Determinants



The relative PE ratio of a firm is determined by two variables. In particular, it will •





increase as the firm’s growth rate relative to the market increases. The rate of change in the relative PE will itself be a function of the market growth rate, with much greater changes when the market growth rate is higher. In other words, a firm or sector with a growth rate twice that of the market will have a much higher relative PE when the market growth rate is 10% than when it is 5%. decrease as the firm’s risk relative to the market increases. The extent of the decrease depends upon how long the firm is expected to stay at this level of relative risk. If the different is permanent, the effect is much greater.

Relative PE ratios seem to be unaffected by the level of rates, which might give them a decided advantage over PE ratios.

Aswath Damodaran

85

Relative PE Ratios: The Auto Sector

Relative PE Ratios: Auto Stocks 1.20

1.00

0.80

Ford Chrysler GM

0.60

0.40

0.20

0.00 1993

Aswath Damodaran

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

86

Using Relative PE ratios



On a relative PE basis, all of the automobile stocks looked cheap in 2000 because they were trading at their lowest relative PE ratios than 1993. Why might the relative PE ratio be lower in 2000 than in 1993?

Aswath Damodaran

87

Relative PE Ratios: US stocks Model Su mmar y Mode l 1

R .467 a

R Square .21 8

Adjusted R Square .217

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 41.97324

a. Predictors: ( Constant), Regr ession Bet a, RELGR, RELPA YO U

Co ef fici entsa,b Unstandard ized Coefficients Mode l 1

(Constant)

B .379

Std. Er ror .03 8

RELPAYO U

4.E-02

.00 9

RELG R

.506

Regr ession B eta

.251

Standar dized Coefficients Beta

t 9.862

Sig. .000

.092

4.161

.000

.02 9

.375

17. 558

.000

.01 7

.298

14. 375

.000

a. Dependent Va riable: RELPE b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran

88

Value/Earnings and Value/Cashflow Ratios

While Price earnings ratios look at the market value of equity relative to earnings to equity investors, Value earnings ratios look at the market value of the operating assets of the firm (Enterprise value or EV) relative to operating earnings or cash flows.  The form of value to cash flow ratios that has the closest parallels in DCF valuation is the value to Free Cash Flow to the Firm, which is defined as: EV/FCFF = (Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt-Cash) EBIT (1-t) - (Cap Ex - Deprecn) - Chg in Working Cap 

Aswath Damodaran

89

Value of Firm/FCFF: Determinants

Reverting back to a two-stage FCFF DCF model, we get: ! (1 + g)n $ FCFF (1 + g) # 1& 0 n FCFF (1+ g)n (1+ g ) " (1+ WACC) % 0 n V0 = + WACC - g (WACC - g )(1 + WACC)n n 

• • • • •

Aswath Damodaran

V0 = Value of the firm (today) FCFF0 = Free Cashflow to the firm in current year g = Expected growth rate in FCFF in extraordinary growth period (first n years) WACC = Weighted average cost of capital gn = Expected growth rate in FCFF in stable growth period (after n years)

90

Value Multiples



Dividing both sides by the FCFF yields, !# (1 + g)n $ (1 + g) 1" (1 + WACC)n % V0 (1+ g)n (1+ gn ) = + n FCFF0 WACC - g (WACC - gn )(1 + WACC)



The value/FCFF multiples is a function of • •

Aswath Damodaran

the cost of capital the expected growth

91

Alternatives to FCFF - EBIT and EBITDA



Most analysts find FCFF to complex or messy to use in multiples (partly because capital expenditures and working capital have to be estimated). They use modified versions of the multiple with the following alternative denominator: • • • •

Aswath Damodaran

after-tax operating income or EBIT(1-t) pre-tax operating income or EBIT net operating income (NOI), a slightly modified version of operating income, where any non-operating expenses and income is removed from the EBIT EBITDA, which is earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization.

92

Value/FCFF Multiples and the Alternatives



    

Assume that you have computed the value of a firm, using discounted cash flow models. Rank the following multiples in the order of magnitude from lowest to highest? Value/EBIT Value/EBIT(1-t) Value/FCFF Value/EBITDA What assumption(s) would you need to make for the Value/EBIT(1-t) ratio to be equal to the Value/FCFF multiple?

Aswath Damodaran

93

Illustration: Using Value/FCFF Approaches to value a firm: MCI Communications

    

MCI Communications had earnings before interest and taxes of $3356 million in 1994 (Its net income after taxes was $855 million). It had capital expenditures of $2500 million in 1994 and depreciation of $1100 million; Working capital increased by $250 million. It expects free cashflows to the firm to grow 15% a year for the next five years and 5% a year after that. The cost of capital is 10.50% for the next five years and 10% after that. The company faces a tax rate of 36%.

V0 = FCFF0 Aswath Damodaran

 (1.15)5  (1.15)  1(1.105)5  .105 -.15

5

(1.15) (1.05) = 31.28 + 5 (.10 - .05)(1.105) 94

Multiple Magic



In this case of MCI there is a big difference between the FCFF and short cut measures. For instance the following table illustrates the appropriate multiple using short cut measures, and the amount you would overpay by if you used the FCFF multiple. Free Cash Flow to the Firm = EBIT (1-t) - Net Cap Ex - Change in Working Capital = 3356 (1 - 0.36) + 1100 - 2500 - 250 = $ 498 million $ Value Correct Multiple FCFF $498 31.28382355 EBIT (1-t) $2,148 7.251163362 EBIT $ 3,356 4.640744552 EBITDA $4,456 3.49513885

Aswath Damodaran

95

Reasons for Increased Use of Value/EBITDA

1. The multiple can be computed even for firms that are reporting net losses, since earnings before interest, taxes and depreciation are usually positive. 2. For firms in certain industries, such as cellular, which require a substantial investment in infrastructure and long gestation periods, this multiple seems to be more appropriate than the price/earnings ratio. 3. In leveraged buyouts, where the key factor is cash generated by the firm prior to all discretionary expenditures, the EBITDA is the measure of cash flows from operations that can be used to support debt payment at least in the short term. 4. By looking at cashflows prior to capital expenditures, it may provide a better estimate of “optimal value”, especially if the capital expenditures are unwise or earn substandard returns. 5. By looking at the value of the firm and cashflows to the firm it allows for comparisons across firms with different financial leverage.

Aswath Damodaran

96

Enterprise Value/EBITDA Multiple



The Classic Definition Value Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt = EBITDA Earnings before Interest, Taxes and Depreciation



The No-Cash Version

Enterprise Value Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt - Cash = EBITDA Earnings before Interest, Taxes and Depreciation

Aswath Damodaran

97

Enterprise Value/EBITDA Distribution - US in January 2004

Aswath Damodaran

98

Value/EBITDA Multiple: Europe, Japan and Emerging Markets in January 2004

Aswath Damodaran

99

The Determinants of Value/EBITDA Multiples: Linkage to DCF Valuation



The value of the operating assets of a firm can be written as:

FCFF1 V0 = WACC - g 

The numerator can be written as follows: FCFF

Aswath Damodaran

= EBIT (1-t) - (Cex - Depr) - Δ Working Capital = (EBITDA - Depr) (1-t) - (Cex - Depr) - Δ Working Capital = EBITDA (1-t) + Depr (t) - Cex - Δ Working Capital

100

From Firm Value to EBITDA Multiples



Now the Value of the firm can be rewritten as, EBITDA (1- t) + Depr (t) - Cex - ! Working Capital Value = WACC - g



Dividing both sides of the equation by EBITDA,

Value (1- t) Depr (t)/EBITDA CEx/EBITDA ! Working Capital/EBITDA = + EBITDA WACC- g WACC -g WACC - g WACC - g

Aswath Damodaran

101

A Simple Example



Consider a firm with the following characteristics: • • • • • •

Aswath Damodaran

Tax Rate = 36% Capital Expenditures/EBITDA = 30% Depreciation/EBITDA = 20% Cost of Capital = 10% The firm has no working capital requirements The firm is in stable growth and is expected to grow 5% a year forever.

102

Calculating Value/EBITDA Multiple



Value = EBITDA

In this case, the Value/EBITDA multiple for this firm can be estimated as follows: (1- .36) .10 -.05

Aswath Damodaran

+

(0.2)(.36) 0.3 0 = 8.24 .10 -.05 .10 - .05 .10 - .05

103

Value/EBITDA Multiples and Taxes

Aswath Damodaran

104

Value/EBITDA and Net Cap Ex

Aswath Damodaran

105

Value/EBITDA Multiples and Return on Capital

Aswath Damodaran

106

Value/EBITDA Multiple: Trucking Companies

Company Name KLLM Trans. Svcs. Ryder System Rollins Truck Leasing Cannon Express Inc. Hunt (J.B.) Yellow Corp. Roadway Express Marten Transport Ltd. Kenan Transport Co. M.S. Carriers Old Dominion Freight Trimac Ltd Matlack Systems XTRA Corp. Covenant Transport Inc Builders Transport Werner Enterprises Landstar Sys. AMERCO USA Truck Frozen Food Express Arnold Inds. Greyhound Lines Inc. USFreightways Golden Eagle Group Inc. Arkansas Best Airlease Ltd. Celadon Group Amer. Freightways Transfinancial Holdings Vitran Corp. 'A' Interpool Inc. Intrenet Inc. Swift Transportation Landair Services CNF Transportation Budget Group Inc Caliber System Knight Transportation Inc Heartland Express Greyhound CDA Transn Corp Mark VII Coach USA Inc US 1 Inds Inc. Average

Aswath Damodaran

Value $ 114.32 $ 5,158.04 $ 1,368.35 $ 83.57 $ 982.67 $ 931.47 $ 554.96 $ 116.93 $ 67.66 $ 344.93 $ 170.42 $ 661.18 $ 112.42 $ 1,708.57 $ 259.16 $ 221.09 $ 844.39 $ 422.79 $ 1,632.30 $ 141.77 $ 164.17 $ 472.27 $ 437.71 $ 983.86 $ 12.50 $ 578.78 $ 73.64 $ 182.30 $ 716.15 $ 56.92 $ 140.68 $ 1,002.20 $ 70.23 $ 835.58 $ 212.95 $ 2,700.69 $ 1,247.30 $ 2,514.99 $ 269.01 $ 727.50 $ 83.25 $ 160.45 $ 678.38 $ 5.60

EBITDA Value/EBITDA $ 48.81 2.34 $ 1,838.26 2.81 $ 447.67 3.06 $ 27.05 3.09 $ 310.22 3.17 $ 292.82 3.18 $ 169.38 3.28 $ 35.62 3.28 $ 19.44 3.48 $ 97.85 3.53 $ 45.13 3.78 $ 174.28 3.79 $ 28.94 3.88 $ 427.30 4.00 $ 64.35 4.03 $ 51.44 4.30 $ 196.15 4.30 $ 95.20 4.44 $ 345.78 4.72 $ 29.93 4.74 $ 34.10 4.81 $ 96.88 4.87 $ 89.61 4.88 $ 198.91 4.95 $ 2.33 5.37 $ 107.15 5.40 $ 13.48 5.46 $ 32.72 5.57 $ 120.94 5.92 $ 8.79 6.47 $ 21.51 6.54 $ 151.18 6.63 $ 10.38 6.77 $ 121.34 6.89 $ 30.38 7.01 $ 366.99 7.36 $ 166.71 7.48 $ 333.13 7.55 $ 28.20 9.54 $ 64.62 11.26 $ 6.99 11.91 $ 12.96 12.38 $ 51.76 13.11 $ (0.17) NA 5.61

107

A Test on EBITDA



Ryder System looks very cheap on a Value/EBITDA multiple basis, relative to the rest of the sector. What explanation (other than misvaluation) might there be for this difference?

Aswath Damodaran

108

Analyzing the Value/EBITDA Multiple



While low value/EBITDA multiples may be a symptom of undervaluation, a few questions need to be answered: • • • •

Aswath Damodaran

Is the operating income next year expected to be significantly lower than the EBITDA for the most recent period? (Price may have dropped) Does the firm have significant capital expenditures coming up? (In the trucking business, the life of the trucking fleet would be a good indicator) Does the firm have a much higher cost of capital than other firms in the sector? Does the firm face a much higher tax rate than other firms in the sector?

109

Value/EBITDA Multiples: Market



The multiple of value to EBITDA varies widely across firms in the market, depending upon: •

• •

Aswath Damodaran

how capital intensive the firm is (high capital intensity firms will tend to have lower value/EBITDA ratios), and how much reinvestment is needed to keep the business going and create growth how high or low the cost of capital is (higher costs of capital will lead to lower Value/EBITDA multiples) how high or low expected growth is in the sector (high growth sectors will tend to have higher Value/EBITDA multiples)

110

US Market: Cross Sectional Regression January 2004 Model Summary Mode l 1

R .583

R Square a

Adjusted R Square

.34 0

.33 8

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 653 .801855 07239

a. Predictor s: ( Constant), Reinvestment Rate, Expected Gr owth in Revenues: next 5 years, Eff Tax Rat e

Co ef fici entsa,b Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

B (Constant)

Std. Er ror

10. 073

.768

-.152

.022

.907 -.015

Eff T ax Rate Expected G rowth in Revenues: next 5 year s Reinvestment Rate

Standardized Coefficie nts Be ta

t

Sig.

13.121

.00 0

-.174

-6.878

.00 0

.039

.563

23.464

.00 0

.006

-.062

-2.420

.01 6

a. Dependent Va riable: EV /EBITDA b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran

111

Europe: Cross Sectional Regression January 2004 Model Summary Mode l 1

R .542 a

Adjusted R Square .292

R Square .293

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 1581.333005721082 000

a. Predictors: ( Constant), Tax Rate , Reinv Rate , Market Debt to Ca pital

Coefficientsa,b Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

(Constant)

B 8.419

Std. Er ror 1.2 79

Mar ket Debt t o Capital

Standardized Coefficie nts Be ta

t 6.580

Sig. .00 0

.58 9

.021

.511

28. 035

.00 0

Reinv Ra te

-.051

.009

-.099

-5.472

.00 0

Tax Rat e

-.152

.029

-.095

-5.236

.00 0

a. Dependent Va riable: EV/EBITDA b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - Weig hted by Marke t Capitalization

Aswath Damodaran

112

Price-Book Value Ratio: Definition







The price/book value ratio is the ratio of the market value of equity to the book value of equity, i.e., the measure of shareholders’ equity in the balance sheet. Price/Book Value = Market Value of Equity Book Value of Equity Consistency Tests: • •

Aswath Damodaran

If the market value of equity refers to the market value of equity of common stock outstanding, the book value of common equity should be used in the denominator. If there is more that one class of common stock outstanding, the market values of all classes (even the non-traded classes) needs to be factored in.

113

Price to Book Value: US stocks

Aswath Damodaran

114

Price to Book: Europe, Japan and Emerging Markets

Aswath Damodaran

115

Price Book Value Ratio: Stable Growth Firm



DPS1 model, Going back to a simple dividend P 0 =discount r ! gn



Defining the return on equity (ROE) = EPS0 / Book Value of Equity, the value of equity can be written as: P0 =

BV 0 * ROE * Payout Ratio * (1 + gn ) r-gn

P0 ROE * Payout Ratio * (1 + g n ) = PBV = BV 0 r-g n



If the return on equity is based upon expected earnings in the next time period, this can be simplified to,

P0 ROE * Payout Ratio = PBV = BV 0 r-g n

Aswath Damodaran

116

Price Book Value Ratio: Stable Growth Firm Another Presentation





This formulation can be simplified even further by relating growth to the return on equity: g = (1 - Payout ratio) * ROE Substituting back into the P/BV equation, P0 ROE - g n = PBV = BV0 r-g n



The price-book value ratio of a stable firm is determined by the differential between the!return on equity and the required rate of return on its projects.

Aswath Damodaran

117

Price Book Value Ratio for High Growth Firm



The Price-book ratio for a high-growth firm can be estimated beginning with a 2-stage discounted cash" flow model: (1+ g)n % ' EPS0 * Payout Ratio * (1 + g) * $ 1 ! # (1+ r) n & EPS0 * Payout Ratio n * (1+ g)n *(1+ g n ) P0 = + r -g (r - g n )(1+ r) n



Dividing both sides of the equation by the book value of equity: ' "$ (1+ g)n % * ROE* Payout Ratio *(1+ g)* 1 ! ) # (1+ r) n & P0 ROE n * Payout Ratio n *(1+ g)n *(1+ g n ) , =) + , BV0 r-g (r - gn )(1+ r)n ) , ( +

where

Aswath Damodaran

ROE = Return on Equity in high-growth period ROEn = Return on Equity in stable growth period

118

PBV Ratio for High Growth Firm: Example

Assume that you have been asked to estimate the PBV ratio for a firm which has the following characteristics: High Growth Phase Stable Growth Phase Length of Period 5 years Forever after year 5 Return on Equity 25% 15% Payout Ratio 20% 60% Growth Rate .80*.25=.20 .4*.15=.06 Beta 1.25 1.00 Cost of Equity 12.875% 11.50% The riskfree rate is 6% and the risk premium used is 5.5%. 

Aswath Damodaran

119

Estimating Price/Book Value Ratio



The price/book value ratio for this firm is:

' 0.25 * 0.2 * (1.20) * ) PBV = ) (.12875 ) (

Aswath Damodaran

"$ * (1.20) 5 % 1! # (1.12875) 5 & 0.15 * 0.6 * (1.20)5 * (1.06) , + = 2.66 .20) (.115 - .06) (1.12875) 5 , , +

120

PBV and ROE: The Key

PBV and ROE: Risk Scenarios 4

3.5

Ratios

2

Price/Book

2.5

Value

3

Beta=0.5 Beta=1 Beta=1.5

1.5

1

0.5

0 10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

ROE

Aswath Damodaran

121

PBV/ROE: European Banks Bank Banca di Roma SpA Commerzbank AG Bayerische Hypo und Vereinsbank AG Intesa Bci SpA Natexis Banques Populaires Almanij NV Algemene Mij voor Nijver Credit Industriel et Commercial Credit Lyonnais SA BNL Banca Nazionale del Lavoro SpA Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena SpA Deutsche Bank AG Skandinaviska Enskilda Banken Nordea Bank AB DNB Holding ASA ForeningsSparbanken AB Danske Bank AS Credit Suisse Group KBC Bankverzekeringsholding Societe Generale Santander Central Hispano SA National Bank of Greece SA San Paolo IMI SpA BNP Paribas Svenska Handelsbanken AB UBS AG Banco Bilbao Vizcaya Argentaria SA ABN Amro Holding NV UniCredito Italiano SpA Rolo Banca 1473 SpA Dexia Average

Aswath Damodaran

Symbol BAHQE COHSO BAXWW BAEWF NABQE ALPK CIECM CREV BAEXC MOGG DEMX SKHS NORDEA DNHLD FOLG DANKAS CRGAL KBCBA SODI BAZAB NAGT SAOEL BNPRB SVKE UBQH BBFUG ABTS UNCZA ROGMBA DECCT

PBV 0.60 0.74 0.82 1.12 1.12 1.17 1.20 1.20 1.22 1.34 1.36 1.39 1.40 1.42 1.61 1.66 1.68 1.69 1.73 1.83 1.87 1.88 2.00 2.12 2.15 2.18 2.21 2.25 2.37 2.76 1.60

ROE 4.15% 5.49% 5.39% 7.81% 7.38% 8.78% 9.46% 6.86% 12.43% 10.86% 17.33% 16.33% 13.69% 16.78% 18.69% 19.09% 14.34% 30.85% 17.55% 11.01% 26.19% 16.57% 18.68% 21.82% 16.64% 22.94% 24.21% 15.90% 16.67% 14.99% 14.96%

122

PBV versus ROE regression





Regressing PBV ratios against ROE for banks yields the following regression: PBV = 0.81 + 5.32 (ROE) R2 = 46% For every 1% increase in ROE, the PBV ratio should increase by 0.0532.

Aswath Damodaran

123

Under and Over Valued Banks?

Bank Banca di Roma SpA Commerzbank AG Bayerische Hypo und Vereinsbank AG Intesa Bci SpA Natexis Banques Populaires Almanij NV Algemene Mij voor Nijver Credit Industriel et Commercial Credit Lyonnais SA BNL Banca Nazionale del Lavoro SpA Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena SpA Deutsche Bank AG Skandinaviska Enskilda Banken Nordea Bank AB DNB Holding ASA ForeningsSparbanken AB Danske Bank AS Credit Suisse Group KBC Bankverzekeringsholding Societe Generale Santander Central Hispano SA National Bank of Greece SA San Paolo IMI SpA BNP Paribas Svenska Handelsbanken AB UBS AG Banco Bilbao Vizcaya Argentaria SA ABN Amro Holding NV UniCredito Italiano SpA Rolo Banca 1473 SpA Dexia

Aswath Damodaran

Actual 0.60 0.74 0.82 1.12 1.12 1.17 1.20 1.20 1.22 1.34 1.36 1.39 1.40 1.42 1.61 1.66 1.68 1.69 1.73 1.83 1.87 1.88 2.00 2.12 2.15 2.18 2.21 2.25 2.37 2.76

Predicted 1.03 1.10 1.09 1.22 1.20 1.27 1.31 1.17 1.47 1.39 1.73 1.68 1.54 1.70 1.80 1.82 1.57 2.45 1.74 1.39 2.20 1.69 1.80 1.97 1.69 2.03 2.10 1.65 1.69 1.61

Under or Over -41.33% -32.86% -24.92% -8.51% -6.30% -7.82% -8.30% 2.61% -16.71% -3.38% -21.40% -17.32% -9.02% -16.72% -10.66% -9.01% 7.20% -30.89% -0.42% 31.37% -15.06% 11.15% 11.07% 7.70% 27.17% 7.66% 5.23% 36.23% 39.74% 72.04%

124

Looking for undervalued securities - PBV Ratios and ROE





Given the relationship between price-book value ratios and returns on equity, it is not surprising to see firms which have high returns on equity selling for well above book value and firms which have low returns on equity selling at or below book value. The firms which should draw attention from investors are those which provide mismatches of price-book value ratios and returns on equity - low P/BV ratios and high ROE or high P/BV ratios and low ROE.

Aswath Damodaran

125

The Valuation Matrix

MV/BV

Overvalued Low ROE High MV/BV

High ROE High MV/BV

ROE-r

Low ROE Low MV/BV

Aswath Damodaran

Undervalued High ROE Low MV/BV

126

Price to Book vs ROE: Largest Market Cap Firms in the United States: September 2003 20 DE LL

SAP

G

BUD

PFE EBAY

10

GS K

BSX

O RCL MMM PG

MDT

DAZN

WMT BMY

Q COM

MRK

K MB

AMAT

PBV Ratio

JNJ

UL MO FNM

ABN SC 0 0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

ROE

Aswath Damodaran

127

PBV Matrix: Telecom Companies

12 TelAzteca

10 TelNZ

8

Vimple

Carlton

Cable&W

Teleglobe FranceTel

6

DeutscheTel BritTel TelItalia BCE

4

Portugal Royal Hellenic

AsiaSat HongKong

Nippon DanmarkChinaTel Espana Telmex TelArgFrance PhilTel TelArgentina

2 APT CallNet Anonima

GrupoCentro

0

10

Televisas TelIndo TelPeru

Indast

0 20

30

40

50

60

ROE

Aswath Damodaran

128

PBV, ROE and Risk: Large Cap US firms

16 14

BUD G PFE

12

O RCL MMM

10

PBV R atio

PG

8 UL

6

MRK

MDT WMT

D QCOM

FNMK MB

4

FRE

2

SC 70 60

50 40

30 20

ROE

Aswath Damodaran

EBAY

10 0

T SM AMAT

AOL V IA/B

0

1

2

3

4

Regressio n Beta

129

IBM: The Rise and Fall and Rise Again

10.00

50.00%

9.00

40.00%

8.00 30.00%

7.00 20.00%

10.00% 5.00 0.00%

Return on Equity

Price to Book

6.00

4.00

-10.00% 3.00

-20.00% 2.00

-30.00%

1.00

0.00

-40.00% 1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

Year PBV

Aswath Damodaran

ROE

130

PBV Ratio Regression: US January 2004 Mod el Su mmar y Mode l 1

R R Square .943 b .889

a

Adjusted R Square .889

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 117.0574933200291

a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R Square measures the proportion of the variability in the dependent varia ble about the origin explained by regre ssion. This CANNOT b e compared to R Squar e for models which include an intercept. b. Predictors: ROE, R egr ession B eta, PAYOU T, Expected Growth in EPS: next 5 year s

Co effici entsa,b,c Unstandardized Coefficients Mode l 1

B Expected G rowth in EPS: next 5 years PAYOUT

Std. Error

Standar dized Coefficients Beta

t

Sig.

8.E-02

.00 4

.256

21.93 5

.000

2.E-03

.00 1

.017

1.551

.121

Regr ession B eta

.599

.04 2

.151

14.24 9

.000

ROE

.140

.00 3

.628

50.73 1

.000

a. Dependent Va riable: PBV Ratio b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin c. Weighted Least Squares R egre ssion - Weig hted by Marke t Cap

Aswath Damodaran

131

PBV Ratio Regression- Europe January 2004 Mod el Summary Mode l 1

R R Square .830 b .689

a

Adjusted R Squar e .689

Std. Error of the Estimate 154.4404 7748882220

a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R Squar e mea sur es the prop or tion of the va riability in the depende nt variable about the origin explained by regression. This CA NNOT be compare d to R Square for models which include an inter cept. b. Predictors: ROE, Payout Ra tio, B ETA

Coefficientsa ,b,c Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

Payout Ratio BE TA ROE

Standardized Coefficie nts

B 8.E-03

Std. Er ror .002

Be ta .074

t 3.667

Sig. .00 0

1.399

.114

.291

12. 279

.00 0

.10 4

.004

.537

28. 148

.00 0

a. Dependent Va riable: PB V b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin c. Weighted Least Squares R egre ssion - Weighted by Marke t Capitalization

Aswath Damodaran

132

PBV Regression: Emerging Markets January 2004 Mod el Summary Mode l 1

a

R R Square .795 b .63 1

Adjusted R Square .631

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 2.0708694 612 34543

a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept m odel) , R Square mea sur es the proportion of the va riability in the d ependent va riable about the origin explained b y regression. This CANNOT be compared to R Square f or models which include an inter cept. b. Predictors: ROE, Payout Ratio, BETA

Coefficientsa ,b Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

Payout Ratio BE TA ROE

Standardized Coefficie nts

B 5.E-03

Std. Er ror .001

Be ta .076

t 4.148

Sig. .00 0

.80 5

.088

.213

9.164

.00 0

9.E-02

.003

.579

29. 414

.00 0

a. Dependent Va riable: PB V b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin

Aswath Damodaran

133

PBV Ratio: Japan in January 2004 Model Su mmar y

Mode l 1

R Net Income > 0 (Selected)

Adjusted R Squar e

R Sq uare a

.815

b

.664

Std. Er ror of the Estimate

.664

848.8652 371625490 00

a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R Square mea sur es the prop or tion of the va riability in the depende nt va riable about the origin explained b y regression. This CANNOT be compare d to R Square for models which include an intercept. Co ef fici entsa,b,c,d b. Predictors: B ETA, ROE Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

B

Standardized Coefficie nts

Std. Er ror

Be ta

t

Sig.

ROE

.189

.007

.597

28.912

.00 0

BE TA

.973

.073

.276

13.359

.00 0

a. Dependent Va riable: PBV b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin c. Weighted Least Square s R egression - Weighted by Mar ket Capitalization d. Selecting only cases for which Net Income > 0

Aswath Damodaran

134

Value/Book Value Ratio: Definition

 

While the price to book ratio is a equity multiple, both the market value and the book value can be stated in terms of the firm. Value/Book Value = Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt Book Value of Equity + Book Value of Debt

Aswath Damodaran

135

Determinants of Value/Book Ratios



To see the determinants of the value/book ratio, consider the simple free cash flow to the firm model:

FCFF1 V0 = WACC - g



Dividing both sides by the book value, we get:

V0 FCFF1 /BV = BV WACC - g 

If we replace, FCFF = EBIT(1-t) - (g/ROC) EBIT(1-t),we get

V0 ROC - g = BV WACC - g Aswath Damodaran

136

Value/Book Ratio: An Example



Consider a stable growth firm with the following characteristics: • • •





Return on Capital = 12% Cost of Capital = 10% Expected Growth = 5%

The value/BV ratio for this firm can be estimated as follows: Value/BV = (.12 - .05)/(.10 - .05) = 1.40 The effects of ROC on growth will increase if the firm has a high growth phase, but the basic determinants will remain unchanged.

Aswath Damodaran

137

Value/Book and the Return Spread

Aswath Damodaran

138

Value/Book Capital Regression - US Model Su mmar y Mode l 1

R .758

R Square a

Adjusted R Square

.575

Std. Er ror of the Estimate

.574

135.06239892 7610600

a. Predictors: ( Constant), Market Debt to Cap ital, Expected Growth in Revenues: next 5 years, ROC

Co ef fici entsa,b Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

B (Constant)

Std. Er ror

3.041

.133

Expected G rowth in Revenues: next 5 year s

1.E-02

.008

ROC

9.E-02 -.066

Marke t Debt to Capital

Standardized Coefficie nts Be ta

t

Sig.

22.838

.00 0

.026

1.3 30

.18 4

.004

.446

22.992

.00 0

.003

-.473

-23.04

.00 0

a. Dependent Va riable: Value/BV of Capital b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran

139

Price Sales Ratio: Definition

 



The price/sales ratio is the ratio of the market value of equity to the sales. Price/ Sales= Market Value of Equity Total Revenues Consistency Tests •

Aswath Damodaran

The price/sales ratio is internally inconsistent, since the market value of equity is divided by the total revenues of the firm.

140

Price/Sales Ratio: US stocks

Revenue Multiples: US Companies in January 2004 600

500

400

300

Price to Sales EV/Sales

200

100

0 10

141

Price to Sales: Europe, Japan and Emerging Markets

Aswath Damodaran

142

Price/Sales Ratio: Determinants



The price/sales ratio of a stable growth firm can be estimated beginning with a 2-stage equity valuation model: P0 =



DPS1 r ! gn

Dividing both sides by the sales per share:

P0 Net Profit Margin* Payout Ratio *(1+ g n ) = PS = Sales 0 r-g n

Aswath Damodaran

143

Price/Sales Ratio for High Growth Firm



When the growth rate is assumed to be high for a future period, the dividend discount model can be written as follows: n

" (1+ g) %' EPS0 * Payout Ratio * (1 + g) * $ 1 ! # (1+ r) n & EPS0 * Payout Ratio n * (1+ g)n *(1+ g n ) P0 = + r -g (r - g n )(1+ r) n



Dividing both sides by the sales per share:

' "$ * (1+ g) n % Net Margin * Payout Ratio * (1+ g)* 1 ! ) # P0 (1+ r)n & Net Marginn * Payout Ratio n * (1+ g) n *(1 + gn ) , = + , Sales 0 ) r -g (r - gn )(1 + r)n ) , ( +

where Net Marginn = Net Margin in stable growth phase

Aswath Damodaran

144

Price Sales Ratios and Profit Margins

 

The key determinant of price-sales ratios is the profit margin. A decline in profit margins has a two-fold effect. • •

First, the reduction in profit margins reduces the price-sales ratio directly. Second, the lower profit margin can lead to lower growth and hence lower pricesales ratios. Expected growth rate = Retention ratio * Return on Equity = Retention Ratio *(Net Profit / Sales) * ( Sales / BV of Equity) = Retention Ratio * Profit Margin * Sales/BV of Equity

Aswath Damodaran

145

Price/Sales Ratio: An Example

Length of Period Net Margin Sales/BV of Equity Beta Payout Ratio Expected Growth Riskless Rate =6%

High Growth Phase 5 years 10% 2.5 1.25 20% (.1)(2.5)(.8)=20%

Stable Growth Forever after year 5 6% 2.5 1.00 60% (.06)(2.5)(.4)=.06

' "$ * (1.20)5 % 0.10 * 0.2 * (1.20) * 1 ! ) # (1.12875)5 & 0.06 * 0.60 * (1.20) 5 * (1.06) , PS = ) + , = 1.06 (.12875 - .20) (.115 -.06) (1.12875) 5 ) , ( +

Aswath Damodaran

146

Effect of Margin Changes

Price/Sales Ratios and Net Margins 1.8

1.6

1.4

PS Ratio

1.2

1

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0 2%

4%

6%

8% Net

Aswath Damodaran

10%

12%

14%

16%

Margin

147

PS/Margins: European Retailers - September 2003

Aswath Damodaran

148

Regression Results: PS Ratios and Margins



 

Regressing PS ratios against net margins, PS = -.39 + 0.6548 (Net Margin) R2 = 43.5% Thus, a 1% increase in the margin results in an increase of 0.6548 in the price sales ratios. The regression also allows us to get predicted PS ratios for these firms

Aswath Damodaran

149

Current versus Predicted Margins 

 



One of the limitations of the analysis we did in these last few pages is the focus on current margins. Stocks are priced based upon expected margins rather than current margins. For most firms, current margins and predicted margins are highly correlated, making the analysis still relevant. For firms where current margins have little or no correlation with expected margins, regressions of price to sales ratios against current margins (or price to book against current return on equity) will not provide much explanatory power. In these cases, it makes more sense to run the regression using either predicted margins or some proxy for predicted margins.

Aswath Damodaran

150

A Case Study: The Internet Stocks

30

PKSI LCOS

20

A d j P S

INTM

SPYG MMXI

SCNT

FFIV

MQST CNET INTW

10 NETO

RAMP

CSGP

APNT SPLN

EDGRPSIX

CLKS

BIDS BIZZ

ONEM -0

CBIS

ABTL

FATB RMII

-0.8

ALOY

IIXL

INFO

TURF

-0.6

ATHY

PPOD GSVI

-0.4

ATHM DCLK NTPA

SONEPCLN AMZN

ITRA

ACOM EGRP ANET TMNT GEEK ELTX BUYX ROWE

-0.2

AdjMargin

Aswath Damodaran

151

PS Ratios and Margins are not highly correlated 

Regressing PS ratios against current margins yields the following PS = 81.36



- 7.54(Net Margin) (0.49)

R2 = 0.04

This is not surprising. These firms are priced based upon expected margins, rather than current margins.

Aswath Damodaran

152

Solution 1: Use proxies for survival and growth: Amazon in early 2000 

Hypothesizing that firms with higher revenue growth and higher cash balances should have a greater chance of surviving and becoming profitable, we ran the following regression: (The level of revenues was used to control for size)

PS = 30.61 - 2.77 ln(Rev) + 6.42 (Rev Growth) + 5.11 (Cash/Rev) (0.66) (2.63) (3.49)

R squared = 31.8% Predicted PS = 30.61 - 2.77(7.1039) + 6.42(1.9946) + 5.11 (.3069) = 30.42 Actual PS = 25.63 Stock is undervalued, relative to other internet stocks.

Aswath Damodaran

153

Solution 2: Use forward multiples  

You can always estimate price (or value) as a multiple of revenues, earnings or book value in a future year. These multiples are called forward multiples. For young and evolving firms, the values of fundamentals in future years may provide a much better picture of the true value potential of the firm. There are two ways in which you can use forward multiples: •



Aswath Damodaran

Look at value today as a multiple of revenues or earnings in the future (say 5 years from now) for all firms in the comparable firm list. Use the average of this multiple in conjunction with your firm’s earnings or revenues to estimate the value of your firm today. Estimate value as a multiple of current revenues or earnings for more mature firms in the group and apply this multiple to the forward earnings or revenues to the forward earnings for your firm. This will yield the expected value for your firm in the forward year and will have to be discounted back to the present to get current value.

154

An Example of Forward Multiples: Global Crossing 

 

Global Crossing lost $1.9 billion in 2001 and is expected to continue to lose money for the next 3 years. In a discounted cashflow valuation (see notes on DCF valuation) of Global Crossing, we estimated an expected EBITDA for Global Crossing in five years of $ 1,371 million. The average enterprise value/ EBITDA multiple for healthy telecomm firms is 7.2 currently. Applying this multiple to Global Crossing’s EBITDA in year 5, yields a value in year 5 of • Enterprise Value in year 5 = 1371 * 7.2 = $9,871 million • Enterprise Value today = $ 9,871 million/ 1.1385 = $5,172 million (The cost of capital for Global Crossing is 13.80%) • The probability that Global Crossing will not make it as a going concern is 77% and the distress sale value is only a $ 1 billion (1/2 of book value of assets). • Adjusted Enterprise value = 5172 * .23 + 1000 (.77) = 1,960 million

Aswath Damodaran

155

PS Regression: United States - January 2004 Mod el Summary Mode l 1

R R Square .932 b .869

Adjusted R Square .868

a

Std. Error of the Estimate 114.3056698264723 0

a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R Square measures the proport ion of the variability in the dependent varia ble about the origin explained by regre ssion. This CANNOT be compared to R Squar e for models which include an intercept. b. Predictors: Net Mar gin, Regression Beta, PAYOUT, Expe cted Growth in EPS: Co next 5 years effici entsa,b,c

Unstandardized Coefficients Mode l 1

B Expected G rowth in EPS: next 5 years PAYOUT

Std. Error

Standar dized Coefficients Beta

t

Sig.

4.E-02

.00 4

.136

10.19 5

.000

-.011

.00 1

-.110

-9.425

.000

Regr ession B eta

.549

.04 3

.156

12.65 8

.000

Net Margin

.234

.00 4

.799

59.92 6

.000

a. Dependent Va riable: PS_RATIO b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin c. Weighted Least Squares R egre ssion - Weig hted by Marke t Cap

Aswath Damodaran

156

PS Regression: Europe in January 2004 Model Summary Mode l 1

a

R R Square .757 b .57 4

Adjusted R Square .573

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 134.938678072015

a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept m odel) , R Sq uare measures the proportion of the variab ility in the dependent varia ble about the origin explained by regression. This CANNO T be compar ed to R Square for models which include an intercept. b. Predictors: Net Mar gin, Payout Ra tio, BETA Coefficientsa ,b,c Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

Standardized Coefficie nts

B 5.E-03

Std. Er ror .002

Be ta .065

t 2.777

Sig. .00 6

BE TA

.93 7

.095

.261

9.909

.00 0

Net Margin

.11 0

.004

.516

26. 153

.00 0

Payout Ratio

a. Dependent Va riable: PS b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin c. Weighted Least Squares R egre ssion - Weighted by Marke t Capitalization

Aswath Damodaran

157

PS Regression in Emerging Markets - January 2004 Model Summary

Mode l 1

R Net Income > .00 (Selected)

R Sq uare a

.834

b

Adjusted R Squar e

.696

.695

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 2.308859441838714

a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R Square measures the proport ion of the variability in the depen dent variable abou t the origin explaine d by re gression. This CANNOT be compared to R Squar e for models which include an intercept. b. Predictors: Net Mar gin, Payout Ra tio, BETA Coefficientsa ,b,c Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

Standardized Coefficie nts

B 7.E-03

Std. Er ror .001

Be ta .083

t 4.962

Sig. .00 0

BE TA

.14 2

.087

.030

1.631

.10 3

Net Margin

.14 3

.003

.766

47. 061

.00 0

Payout Ratio

a. Dependent Va riable: PS b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin c. Selecting only cases for which Ne t Income > .00

Aswath Damodaran

158

PS Regression in Japan: January 2004 Model Summary

Mode l 1

R Net Income > 0 (Selected) .721

R Sq uare a

Adjusted R Squar e

.519

.518

Std. Er ror of the Estimate 549.1390 58787986000

a. Predictors: ( Constant), Payout Ratio, Net Mar gin

Coefficientsa ,b,c Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

(Constant)

B 2.E-02

Std. Er ror .081

Net Margin

.24 3

.007

8.E-03

.002

Payout Ratio

Standardized Coefficie nts Be ta

t .242

Sig. .80 8

.737

34. 627

.00 0

.079

3.719

.00 0

a. Dependent Va riable: PS b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighted by Mar ket Capitalization c. Selecting only cases for which Ne t Income > 0

Aswath Damodaran

159

Value/Sales Ratio: Definition

 

The value/sales ratio is the ratio of the market value of the firm to the sales. Value/ Sales= Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt-Cash Total Revenues

Aswath Damodaran

160

Value/Sales Ratios: Analysis of Determinants



If pre-tax operating margins are used, the appropriate value estimate is that of the firm. In particular, if one makes the assumption that •



Free Cash Flow to the Firm = EBIT (1 - tax rate) (1 - Reinvestment Rate)

Then the Value of the Firm can be written as a function of the after-tax operating margin= (EBIT (1-t)/Sales

n ( + " % (1 + g) *(1 - RIRgrowth)(1 + g) * $1 ! n' n (1 + WACC) & Value (1 - RIR stable)(1 + g) * (1 + g n ) # * = After - tax Oper. Margin * + * Sales 0 WACC - g (WACC - g n )(1 + WACC) n * ) ,

g = Growth rate in after-tax operating income for the first n years gn = Growth rate in after-tax operating income after n years forever (Stable growth rate) RIRGrowth, Stable = Reinvestment rate in high growth and stable periods WACC = Weighted average cost of capital

Aswath Damodaran

161

Value/Sales Ratio: An Example



Consider, for example, the Value/Sales ratio of Coca Cola. The company had the following characteristics: After-tax Operating Margin =18.56% Sales/BV of Capital = 1.67 Return on Capital = 1.67* 18.56% = 31.02% Reinvestment Rate= 65.00% in high growth; 20% in stable growth; Expected Growth = 31.02% * 0.65 =20.16% (Stable Growth Rate=6%) Length of High Growth Period = 10 years Cost of Equity =12.33% E/(D+E) = 97.65% After-tax Cost of Debt = 4.16% D/(D+E) 2.35% Cost of Capital= 12.33% (.9765)+4.16% (.0235) =12.13%

( + " (1.2016)1 0 % * (1- .65)(1.2016)* $1! 10' 1 0 Value of Firm 0 (1- .20)(1.2016) * (1.06) # (1.1213) & * = .1856* + = 6.10 * Sales 0 .1213- .2016 (.1213- .06)(1.1213)1 0 * ) ,

Aswath Damodaran

162

Value Sales Ratios and Operating Margins

Aswath Damodaran

163

U.S. Specialty Retailers: V/S vs Operating Margin 2.0

CDWC

LUX

CHCS

ISEE

DABR

MBAY

VVTV

BID

TOO BFCI SCC

1.5 TWTR

CPWM

HOTT

TLB PCCC V / S a l e s

WSM

SATH

JWL

1.0 BBY NSIT

CWTRMIKE LIN SCHS

LE

GBIZ

VOXX JILL SAH

FLWS

ROSI MHCO

-0.0

MSEL

-0.000

Aswath Damodaran

PBY CHRS

Z CLWY RUSH LVC

PSRC GDYS RET.TO

MNRO CAO

ITN PGDA

CC

0.5 MTMC ANIC CELL

ORLY ZLC LTD AZO IPAR ANN ZQK PIR RAYS MDLK MENS

GADZ

SPGLA

FINL

CLE FOSL

GLBE HLYW RUS

DAP

BEBE ROST

HMY FNLY

PLCE

PSUN

URBN BKE

PSS DBRN

AEOS

WLSN

IBI MDA

TWMC

ZANY MLG

0.075

0.150 Operating Margin

0.225

164

Brand Name Premiums in Valuation



  

You have been hired to value Coca Cola for an analyst reports and you have valued the firm at 6.10 times revenues, using the model described in the last few pages. Another analyst is arguing that there should be a premium added on to reflect the value of the brand name. Do you agree? Yes No Explain.

Aswath Damodaran

165

The value of a brand name

  



One of the critiques of traditional valuation is that is fails to consider the value of brand names and other intangibles. The approaches used by analysts to value brand names are often ad-hoc and may significantly overstate or understate their value. One of the benefits of having a well-known and respected brand name is that firms can charge higher prices for the same products, leading to higher profit margins and hence to higher price-sales ratios and firm value. The larger the price premium that a firm can charge, the greater is the value of the brand name. In general, the value of a brand name can be written as: Value of brand name ={(V/S)b-(V/S)g }* Sales (V/S)b = Value of Firm/Sales ratio with the benefit of the brand name (V/S)g = Value of Firm/Sales ratio of the firm with the generic product

Aswath Damodaran

166

Illustration: Valuing a brand name: Coca Cola

AT Operating Margin Sales/BV of Capital ROC Reinvestment Rate Expected Growth Length Cost of Equity E/(D+E) AT Cost of Debt D/(D+E) Cost of Capital Value/Sales Ratio

Aswath Damodaran

Coca Cola 18.56% 1.67 31.02% 65.00% (19.35%) 20.16% 10 years 12.33% 97.65% 4.16% 2.35% 12.13% 6.10

Generic Cola Company 7.50% 1.67 12.53% 65.00% (47.90%) 8.15% 10 yea 12.33% 97.65% 4.16% 2.35% 12.13% 0.69

167

Value of Coca Cola’s Brand Name



 

Value of Coke’s Brand Name= ( 6.10 - 0.69) ($18,868 million) = $102 billion Value of Coke as a company = 6.10 ($18,868 million) = $ 115 Billion Approximately 88.69% of the value of the company can be traced to brand name value

Aswath Damodaran

168

Value/Sales Ratio Regression: US in January 2004 Model Summary Mode l 1

R .726 a

R Square .527

Adjusted R Square .526

Std. Error of the Estimate 150 .9882839615558

a. Predictors: ( Constant), Expected G rowth in Revenue s: next 5 year s, After-tax Oper ating Ma rgin, Mar ket Debt t o Capital

Co ef fici entsa,b Unstandardized Coefficie nts Mode l 1

(Constant) After-tax Oper ating Margin Marke t Debt to Capital Expected G rowth in Revenues: next 5 year s

B 1.252

Std. Er ror .118

.135

.004

-.043 8.E-02

Standardized Coefficie nts Be ta

t 10.576

Sig. .00 0

.605

32.945

.00 0

.003

-.300

-14.99

.00 0

.009

.175

8.7 56

.00 0

a. Dependent Va riable: EV /Sales b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran

169

Choosing Between the Multiples   

As presented in this section, there are dozens of multiples that can be potentially used to value an individual firm. In addition, relative valuation can be relative to a sector (or comparable firms) or to the entire market (using the regressions, for instance) Since there can be only one final estimate of value, there are three choices at this stage: • • •

Aswath Damodaran

Use a simple average of the valuations obtained using a number of different multiples Use a weighted average of the valuations obtained using a nmber of different multiples Choose one of the multiples and base your valuation on that multiple

170

Averaging Across Multiples   

This procedure involves valuing a firm using five or six or more multiples and then taking an average of the valuations across these multiples. This is completely inappropriate since it averages good estimates with poor ones equally. If some of the multiples are “sector based” and some are “market based”, this will also average across two different ways of thinking about relative valuation.

Aswath Damodaran

171

Weighted Averaging Across Multiples 





In this approach, the estimates obtained from using different multiples are averaged, with weights on each based upon the precision of each estimate. The more precise estimates are weighted more and the less precise ones weighted less. The precision of each estimate can be estimated fairly simply for those estimated based upon regressions as follows: Precision of Estimate = 1 / Standard Error of Estimate where the standard error of the predicted value is used in the denominator. This approach is more difficult to use when some of the estimates are subjective and some are based upon more quantitative techniques.

Aswath Damodaran

172

Picking one Multiple 



This is usually the best way to approach this issue. While a range of values can be obtained from a number of multiples, the “best estimate” value is obtained using one multiple. The multiple that is used can be chosen in one of two ways: • •



Aswath Damodaran

Use the multiple that best fits your objective. Thus, if you want the company to be undervalued, you pick the multiple that yields the highest value. Use the multiple that has the highest R-squared in the sector when regressed against fundamentals. Thus, if you have tried PE, PBV, PS, etc. and run regressions of these multiples against fundamentals, use the multiple that works best at explaining differences across firms in that sector. Use the multiple that seems to make the most sense for that sector, given how value is measured and created.

173

Self Serving Multiple Choice  

 

When a firm is valued using several multiples, some will yield really high values and some really low ones. If there is a significant bias in the valuation towards high or low values, it is tempting to pick the multiple that best reflects this bias. Once the multiple that works best is picked, the other multiples can be abandoned and never brought up. This approach, while yielding very biased and often absurd valuations, may serve other purposes very well. As a user of valuations, it is always important to look at the biases of the entity doing the valuation, and asking some questions: • •

Aswath Damodaran

Why was this multiple chosen? What would the value be if a different multiple were used? (You pick the specific multiple that you want to see tried.)

174

The Statistical Approach 





One of the advantages of running regressions of multiples against fundamentals across firms in a sector is that you get R-squared values on the regression (that provide information on how well fundamentals explain differences across multiples in that sector). As a rule, it is dangerous to use multiples where valuation fundamentals (cash flows, risk and growth) do not explain a significant portion of the differences across firms in the sector. As a caveat, however, it is not necessarily true that the multiple that has the highest R-squared provides the best estimate of value for firms in a sector.

Aswath Damodaran

175

A More Intuitive Approach 

Managers in every sector tend to focus on specific variables when analyzing strategy and performance. The multiple used will generally reflect this focus. Consider three examples. • •



Aswath Damodaran

In retailing: The focus is usually on same store sales (turnover) and profit margins. Not surprisingly, the revenue multiple is most common in this sector. In financial services: The emphasis is usually on return on equity. Book Equity is often viewed as a scarce resource, since capital ratios are based upon it. Price to book ratios dominate. In technology: Growth is usually the dominant theme. PEG ratios were invented in this sector.

176

Conventional Usage: A Summary 

As a general rule of thumb, the following table provides a way of picking a multiple for a sector

Sector Cyclical Manufacturing High Tech, High Growth High Growth/No Earnings Heavy Infrastructure

REITa Financial Services Retailing

Aswath Damodaran

Multiple Used PE, Relative PE PEG

Rationale Often with normalized earnings Big differences in growth across firms PS, VS Assume future margins will be good VEBITDA Firms in sector have losses in early years and reported earnings can vary depending on depreciation method P/CF Generally no cap ex investments from equity earnings PBV Book value often marked to market PS If leverage is similar across firms VS If leverage is different

177

Sector or Market Multiples  

The conventional approach to using multiples is to look at the sector or comparable firms. Whether sector or market based multiples make the most sense depends upon how you think the market makes mistakes in valuation •

• 

If you think that markets make mistakes on individual firm valuations but that valuations tend to be right, on average, at the sector level, you will use sectorbased valuation only, If you think that markets make mistakes on entire sectors, but is generally right on the overall market level, you will use only market-based valuation

It is usually a good idea to approach the valuation at two levels: • •

Aswath Damodaran

At the sector level, use multiples to see if the firm is under or over valued at the sector level At the market level, check to see if the under or over valuation persists once you correct for sector under or over valuation.

178

A Test You have valued Earthlink Networks, an internet service provider, relative to other internet companies using Price/Sales ratios and find it to be under valued almost 50% .When you value it relative to the market, using the market regression, you find it to be overvalued by almost 50%. How would you reconcile the two findings?  One of the two valuations must be wrong. A stock cannot be under and over valued at the same time.  It is possible that both valuations are right. What has to be true about valuations in the sector for the second statement to be true? 

Aswath Damodaran

179

Reviewing: The Four Steps to Understanding Multiples



Define the multiple • •



Describe the multiple • •



Multiples have skewed distributions: The averages are seldom good indicators of typical multiples Check for bias, if the multiple cannot be estimated

Analyze the multiple • •



Check for consistency Make sure that they are estimated uniformly

Identify the companion variable that drives the multiple Examine the nature of the relationship

Apply the multiple

Aswath Damodaran

180

Private Company Valuation Aswath Damodaran

Aswath Damodaran

181

Process of Valuing Private Companies 

Choosing the right model • •



Valuing the Firm versus Valuing Equity Steady State, Two-Stage or Three-Stage

Estimating a Discount Rate •

Cost of Equity – Estimating Betas



Cost of Debt – Estimating Default Risk – Estimating an after-tax cost of debt



Cost of Capital – Estimating a Debt Ratio

 

Estimating Cash Flows Completing the Valuation: Depends upon why and for whom the valuation is being done.

Aswath Damodaran

182

Private Company Valuation: Motive matters 

You can value a private company for • • • • •



Legal purposes: Estate tax and divorce court Sale or prospective sale to another individual or private entity. Sale of one partner’s interest to another Sale to a publicly traded firm As prelude to setting offering price in an initial public offering

You can value a division or divisions of a publicly traded firm • • •

Aswath Damodaran

As prelude to a spin off For sale to another entity To do a sum-of-the-parts valuation to determine whether a firm will be worth more broken up or if it is being efficiently run.

183

Estimating Cost of Equity for a Private Firm   

Most models of risk and return (including the CAPM and the APM) use past prices of an asset to estimate its risk parameters (beta(s)). Private firms and divisions of firms are not traded, and thus do not have past prices. Thus, risk estimation has to be based upon an approach that does not require past prices

Aswath Damodaran

184

I. Comparable Firm Betas 

Collect a group of publicly traded comparable firms, preferably in the same line of business, but more generally, affected by the same economic forces that affect the firm being valued. •



A Simple Test: To see if the group of comparable firms is truly comparable, estimate a correlation between the revenues or operating income of the comparable firms and the firm being valued. If it is high (and positive), of course, your have comparable firms.

If the private firm operates in more than one business line collect comparable firms for each business line

Aswath Damodaran

185

Estimating comparable firm betas  



Estimate the average beta for the publicly traded comparable firms. Estimate the average market value debt-equity ratio of these comparable firms, and calculate the unlevered beta for the business. βunlevered = βlevered / (1 + (1 - tax rate) (Debt/Equity)) Estimate a debt-equity ratio for the private firm, using one of two assumptions: •

Assume that the private firm will move to the industry average debt ratio. The beta for the private firm will converge on the industry average beta.

β private firm = βunlevered (1 + (1 - tax rate) (Industry Average Debt/Equity)) •



Estimate the optimal debt ratio for the private firm, based upon its operating income and cost of capital.

β private firm = βunlevered (1 + (1 - tax rate) (Optimal Debt/Equity)) Estimate a cost of equity based upon this beta.

Aswath Damodaran

186

Accounting Betas     

Step 1: Collect accounting earnings for the private company for as long as there is a history. Step 2: Collect accounting earnings for the S&P 500 for the same time period. Step 3: Regress changes in earnings for the private company against changes in the S&P 500. Step 4: The slope of the regression is the accounting beta There are two serious limitations (a) The number of observations in the regression is small (b) Accountants smooth earnings.

Aswath Damodaran

187

Estimating a Beta for the NY Yankees 

You have three choices for comparable firms: • • •

Firms that derive a significant portion of their revenues from baseball (Traded baseball teams, baseball cards & memorabilia…) Firms that derive a significant portion of their revenues from sports Firms that derive a significant portion of their revenues from entertainment.

Comparable firms Levered Beta Unlevered Beta Baseball firms (2) 0.70 0.64 Sports firms (22) 0.98 0.90 Entertainment firms (91) 0.87 0.79 Management target  Levered Beta for Yankees = 0.90 ( 1 + (1-.4) (.25)) = 1.04  Cost of Equity = 6.00% + 1.04 (4%) = 10.16%

Aswath Damodaran

188

Estimating a beta for InfoSoft: A private software firm Comparable firms include all software firms, with market capitalization of less than $ 500 million.  The average beta for these firms is 1.29 and the average debt to equity ratio for these firms is 7.09%. With a 35% tax rate, this yields an unlevered beta of Unlevered Beta = 1.29/ (1 + (1-.35) (.0709)) = 1.24  We will assume that InfoSoft will have a debt to equity ratio comparable to the average for the comparable firms and a similar tax rate, which results in a levered beta of 1.29.  Cost of Equity = 6.00% + 1.29 (4%) = 11.16% 

Aswath Damodaran

189

Is beta a good measure of risk for a private firm? 

 

The beta of a firm measures only market risk, and is based upon the assumption that the investor in the business is well diversified. Given that private firm owners often have all or the bulk of their wealth invested in the private business, would you expect their perceived costs of equity to be higher or lower than the costs of equity from using betas? Higher Lower

Aswath Damodaran

190

Total Risk versus Market Risk 

Adjust the beta to reflect total risk rather than market risk. This adjustment is a relatively simple one, since the correlation with the market measures the proportion of the risk that is market risk. Total Beta = Market Beta / Correlation with market



In the New York Yankees example, where the market beta is 0.85 and the Rsquared for comparable firms is 25% (correlation is therefore 0.5), • • •

Aswath Damodaran

Total Unlevered Beta = 0.90/0. 5= 1.80 Total Levered Beta = 1.80 (1 + (1-0.4)(0.25)) =2.07 Total Cost of Equity = 6% + 2.07 (4%)= 14.28%

191

When would you use this total risk measure?     

Under which of the following scenarios are you most likely to use the total risk measure: when valuing a private firm for an initial public offering when valuing a private firm for sale to a publicly traded firm when valuing a private firm for sale to another private investor Assume that you own a private business. What does this tell you about the best potential buyer for your business?

Aswath Damodaran

192

Estimating the Cost of Debt for a Private Firm  

Basic Problem: Private firms generally do not access public debt markets, and are therefore not rated. Most debt on the books is bank debt, and the interest expense on this debt might not reflect the rate at which they can borrow (especially if the bank debt is old.)

Aswath Damodaran

193

Estimation Options for Cost of Debt 

Solution 1: Assume that the private firm can borrow at the same rate as similar firms (in terms of size) in the industry. Cost of Debt for Private firm = Cost of Debt for similar firms in the industry



Solution 2: Estimate an appropriate bond rating for the company, based upon financial ratios, and use the interest rate estimated bond rating. Cost of Debt for Private firm = Interest Rate based upon estimated bond rating (If using optimal debt ratio, use corresponding rating)



Solution 3: If the debt on the books of the company is long term and recent, the cost of debt can be calculated using the interest expense and the debt outstanding. Cost of Debt for Private firm = Interest Expense / Outstanding Debt If the firm borrowed the money towards the end of the financial year, the interest expenses for the year will not reflect the interest rate on the debt.

Aswath Damodaran

194

Estimating a Cost of Debt for Yankees and InfoSoft 

For the Yankee’s, we will use the interest rate from the most recent loans that the firm has taken on: • •



Interest rate on debt = 7.00% After-tax cost of debt = 7% (1-.4) = 4.2%

For InfoSoft, we will use the interest coverage ratio estimated using the operating income and interest expenses from the most recent year: • • • •

Aswath Damodaran

Interest coverage ratio = EBIT/ Interest expenses = 2000/315 = 6.35 Rating based upon interest coverage ratio = A+ Interest rate on debt = 6% + 0.80% = 6.80% After-tax cost of debt = 6.80% (1-.35) = 4.42%

195

Estimating the Cost of Capital 



Basic problem: The debt ratios for private firms are stated in book value terms, rather than market value. Furthermore, the debt ratio for a private firm that plans to go public might change as a consequence of that action. Solution 1: Assume that the private firm will move towards the industry average debt ratio. Debt Ratio for Private firm = Industry Average Debt Ratio



Solution 2: Assume that the private firm will move towards its optimal debt ratio. Debt Ratio for Private firm = Optimal Debt Ratio



Consistency in assumptions: The debt ratio assumptions used to calculate the beta, the debt rating and the cost of capital weights should be consistent.

Aswath Damodaran

196

Estimating Costs of Capital

Cost of Equity E/ (D+E) Cost of Debt AT Cost of Debt D/(D+E) Cost of Capital

Aswath Damodaran

New York Yankees 14.28%(total beta) 80.00% 7.00% 4.20% 20.00% 12.26%

InfoSoft Corporation 11.16%(market beta) 93.38% 6.80% 4.42% 6.62% 10.71%

197

Estimating Cash Flows for a Private Firm 



 

Shorter history: Private firms often have been around for much shorter time periods than most publicly traded firms. There is therefore less historical information available on them. Different Accounting Standards: The accounting statements for private firms are often based upon different accounting standards than public firms, which operate under much tighter constraints on what to report and when to report. Intermingling of personal and business expenses: In the case of private firms, some personal expenses may be reported as business expenses. Separating “Salaries” from “Dividends”: It is difficult to tell where salaries end and dividends begin in a private firm, since they both end up with the owner.

Aswath Damodaran

198

Estimating Private Firm Cash Flows 

Restate earnings, if necessary, using consistent accounting standards. •

 

To get a measure of what is reasonable, look at profit margins of comparable publicly traded firms in the same business

If any of the expenses are personal, estimate the income without these expenses. Estimate a “reasonable” salary based upon the services the owner provides the firm.

Aswath Damodaran

199

The Yankee’s Revenues

Net Home Game Receipts Road Receipts Concessions & Parking National TV Revenues Local TV Revenues National Licensing Stadium Advertising Other Revenues

Pittsburg Pirates $ 22,674,597 $ 1,613,172 $ 3,755,965 $ 15,000,000 $ 11,000,000 $ 4,162,747 $ 100,000 $ 1,000,000

Baltimore Orioles $ 47,353,792 $ 7,746,030 $ 22,725,449 $ 15,000,000 $ 18,183,000 $ 3,050,949 $ 4,391,383 $ 9,200,000

New York Yankees $ 52,000,000 $ 9,000,000 $ 25,500,000 $ 15,000,000 $ 90,000,000 $ 6,000,000 $ 5,500,000 $ 6,000,000

Total Revenues

$ 59,306,481

$ 127,650,602

$ 209,000,000

Aswath Damodaran

200

The Yankee’s Expenses

Player Salaries Team Operating Expenses Player Development Stadium & Game Operations$ Other Player Costs G & A Costs Broadcasting Rent & Amortization Total Operating Expenses

Aswath Damodaran

Pittsburg Pirates $ 33,155,366 $ 6,239,025 $ 8,136,551 5,270,986 $ 2,551,000 $ 6,167,617 $ 1,250,000 $ $ 62,770,545

Baltimore Orioles $ 62,771,482 $ 6,803,907 $ 12,768,399 $ 4,869,790 $ 6,895,751 $ 9,321,151 $ $ 6,252,151 $ 109,682,631

New York Yankees $ 91,000,000 $ 7,853,000 $ 15,000,000 $ 7,800,000 $ 7,500,000 $ 11,000,000 $ $ $ 140,153,000

201

Adjustments to Operating Income

Total Revenues Total Operating Expenses EBIT Adjustments Adjusted EBIT Taxes (at 40%) EBIT (1-tax rate)

Aswath Damodaran

Pittsburg Pirates $59,306,481 $62,770,545 -$3,464,064 $1,500,000 -$1,964,064 -$785,626 -$1,178,439

Baltimore Orioles $127,650,602 $109,682,631 $17,967,971 $2,200,000 $20,167,971 $8,067,189 $12,100,783

New York Yankees $209,000,000 $140,153,000 $68,847,000 $4,500,000 $73,347,000 $29,338,800 $44,008,200

202

InfoSoft’s Operating Income Stated Operating Income Sales & Other Operating Revenues - Operating Costs & Expenses - Depreciation - Research and Development Expenses Operating Income

$20,000.00 $13,000.00 $1,000.00 $4,000.00 $2,000.00

Adjusted Operating Income Operating Income

$ 2000.00

+ R& D Expenses - Amortization of Research Asset

$ 4000.00 $ 2311.00

Adjusted Operating Income

$ 3689.00

Aswath Damodaran

203

Estimating Cash Flows for Yankees 

 

We will assume a 3% growth rate in perpetuity for operating income. To generate this growth, we will assume that the Yankee’s will earn 20% on their new investments. This yields a reinvestment rate of Reinvestment rate = g/ ROC = 3%/20% = 15% Estimated Free Cash Flow to Firm

EBIT (1- tax rate) = - Reinvestment = $ FCFF

Aswath Damodaran

$ 44,008,200 6,601,230 $ 37,406,970

204

From Cash Flows to Value  

Once you have estimated the cash flows and the cost of capital, you can value a private firm using conventional methods. If you are valuing a firm for sale to a private business, • •



Use the total beta and the cost of equity emerging from that to estimate the cost of capital. Discount the cash flows using this cost of capital

If you are valuing a firm for an initial public offering, stay with the market beta and cost of capital.

Aswath Damodaran

205

Valuing the Yankees FCFF = $ 37,406,970 Cost of capital = 12.26% Expected Growth rate= 3.00% Value of Yankees = $ 37,406,970 (1.03)/(.1226-.03) = $ 415,902,192

Aswath Damodaran

206

What if? 

We are assuming that the Yankees have to reinvest to generate growth. If they can get the city to pick up the tab, the value of the Yankees can be estimated as follows: • •



FCFF = EBIT (1-t) - Reinvestment = $44.008 mil - 0 = $ 44.008 million Value of Yankees = 44.008*1.03/(.1226 - .03) = $ 489 million

If on top of this, we assume that the buyer is a publicly traded firm and we use the market beta instead of the total beta • • •

Aswath Damodaran

FCFF = $ 44.008 million Cost of capital = 8.95% Value of Yankees = 44.008 (1.03) / (.0895 - .03) = $ 761.6 million

207

InfoSoft: A Valuation Current Cashflow to Firm Reinvestment Rate EBIT(1-t) : 2,933 106.82% - Nt CpX 2,633 - Chg WC 500 = FCFF Reinvestment Rate = 106.82%

Return on Capital 23.67%

Expected Growth in EBIT (1-t) 1.1217*.2367 = .2528 25.28%

Stable Growth g = 5%; Beta = 1.20; D/(D+E) = 6.62%;ROC=17.2% Reinvestment Rate=29.07% Terminal Value10 = 6743/(.1038-.05) = 125,391

Firm Value: + Cash: - Debt: =Equity

73,909 500 4,583 69,826

EBIT(1t) - Reinv FCFF

3675 3926 -251

4604 4918 -314

5768 6161 -393

7227 7720 -493

9054 9671 -617

9507 2764 6743

Discount at Cost of Capital (WACC) = 11.16% (0.9338) + 4.42% (0.0662) = 10.71%

Cost of Equity 11.16%

Cost of Debt (6+0.80%)(1-.35) = 4.42%

Riskfree Rate: Government Bond Rate = 6%

+

Beta 1.29

Unlevered Beta for Sectors: 1.24

Aswath Damodaran

Weights E = 93.38% D = 6.62%

X

Risk Premium 4%

Firm’s D/E Ratio: 7.09%

Historical US Premium 4%

Country Risk Premium 0%

208

Play investment banker: Price this IPO 

The value of equity that we have arrived at for Infosoft is $69.5 million. If you plan to have 10 million shares outstanding, estimate the value per share?



Would this also be your offering price? If not, why not?



Would you answer be different, if the initial offering were for only 1 million shares - the owners will retain the remaining 9 million for subsequent offerings?

Aswath Damodaran

209

Valuation Motives and the Next Step in Private Company Valuation: Control and Illiquidity 

If valuing a private business for sale (in whole or part) to another individual (to stay private), it is necessary that we estimate • •



If valuing a business for taking public, it is necessary to estimate • •



a illiquidity discount associated with the fact that private businesses cannot be easily bought and sold a control premium (if more than 50% of the business is being sold) the effects of creating different classes of shares in the initial public offer the effects of options or warrants on the issuance price per share

If valuing a business for sale (in whole or part) to a publicly traded firm, there should be no illiquidity discount, because stock in the parent firm will trade but there may, however, be a premium associated with the publicly traded firm being able to take better advantage of the private firm’s strengths

Aswath Damodaran

210

Conventional Practice on Illiquidity  

In private company valuation, illiquidity is a constant theme that analysts talk about. All the talk, though, seems to lead to a rule of thumb. The illiquidity discount for a private firm is between 20-30% and does not vary across private firms.

Aswath Damodaran

211

Determinants of the Illiquidity Discount    



Type of Assets owned by the Firm: The more liquid the assets owned by the firm, the lower should be the illiquidity discount for the firm Size of the Firm: The larger the firm, the smaller should be the percentage illiquidity discount. Health of the Firm: Healthier firms should sell for a smaller discount than troubled firms. Cash Flow Generating Capacity: Firms which are generating large amounts of cash from operations should sell for a smaller discounts than firms which do not generate large cash flows. Size of the Block: The liquidity discount should increase with the size of the portion of the firm being sold.

Aswath Damodaran

212

Illiquidity Discounts and Type of Business 

   

Rank the following assets (or private businesses) in terms of the liquidity discount you would apply to your valuation (from biggest discount to smallest) A New York City Cab Medallion A small privately owned five-and-dime store in your town A large privately owned conglomerate, with significant cash balances and real estate holdings. A large privately owned ski resort that is losing money

Aswath Damodaran

213

Empirical Evidence on Illiquidity Discounts: Restricted Stock 

Restricted securities are securities issued by a company, but not registered with the SEC, that can be sold through private placements to investors, but cannot be resold in the open market for a two-year holding period, and limited amounts can be sold after that. Restricted securities trade at significant discounts on publicly traded shares in the same company. •

• •

Aswath Damodaran

Maher examined restricted stock purchases made by four mutual funds in the period 1969-73 and concluded that they traded an average discount of 35.43% on publicly traded stock in the same companies. Moroney reported a mean discount of 35% for acquisitions of 146 restricted stock issues by 10 investment companies, using data from 1970. In a recent study of this phenomenon, Silber finds that the median discount for restricted stock is 33.75%.

214

Cross Sectional Differences : Restricted Stock 

Silber (1991) develops the following relationship between the size of the discount and the characteristics of the firm issuing the registered stock – LN(RPRS) = 4.33 +0.036 LN(REV) - 0.142 LN(RBRT) + 0.174 DERN + 0.332 DCUST where, RPRS = Relative price of restricted stock (to publicly traded stock) REV = Revenues of the private firm (in millions of dollars) RBRT = Restricted Block relative to Total Common Stock in % DERN = 1 if earnings are positive; 0 if earnings are negative; DCUST = 1 if there is a customer relationship with the investor; 0 otherwise;



Interestingly, Silber finds no effect of introducing a control dummy - set equal to one if there is board representation for the investor and zero otherwise.

Aswath Damodaran

215

Adjusting the average illiquidity discount for firm characteristics - Silber Regression  

The Silber regression does provide us with a sense of how different the discount will be for a firm with small revenues versus one with large revenues. Consider, for example, two profitable firms that are equal in every respect except for revenues. Assume that the first firm has revenues of 10 million and the second firm has revenues of 100 million. The Silber regression predicts illiquidity discounts of the following: • • •



For firm with 100 million in revenues: 44.5% For firm with 10 million in revenues: 48.9% Difference in illiquidity discounts: 4.4%

If your base discount for a firm with 10 million in revenues is 25%, the illiquidity discount for a firm with 100 million in revenues would be 20.6%.

Aswath Damodaran

216

Liquidity Discount and Revenues Figure 24.1: Illiquidity Discounts: Base Discount of 25% for profitable firm with $ 10 million in revenues 40.00%

35.00%

Discount as % of Value

30.00%

25.00%

20.00%

15.00%

10.00%

5.00%

0.00% 5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

100

200

300

400

500

1000

Revenues Profitable firm

Aswath Damodaran

Unprofitable firm

217

Application to the Yankees 



 

To estimate the illiquidity discount for the Yankees, we assume that the base discount for a firm with $10 million in revenues would be 25%. The Yankee’s revenues of $209 million should result in a lower discount on their value. We estimate the difference in the illiquidity discount between a firm with $10 million in revenue and $209 million in revenue to be 5.90%. To do this, we first estimated the illiquidity discount in the Silber equation for a firm with $10 million in revenues. Expected illiquidity discount = 48.94% We then re-estimated the illiquidity discount with revenues of $ 209 million: Expected illiquidity discount = 43.04% Difference in discount = 48.94% - 43.04% = 5.90% The estimated illiquidity discount for the Yankees would therefore be 19.10%, which is the base discount of 25% adjusted for the illiquidty difference.

Aswath Damodaran

218

An Alternate Approach to the Illiquidity Discount: Bid Ask Spread   

The bid ask spread is the difference between the price at which you can buy a security and the price at which you can sell it, at the same point. In other words, it is the illiqudity discount on a publicly traded stock. Studies have tied the bid-ask spread to • • •



the size of the firm the trading volume on the stock the degree

Regressing the bid-ask spread against variables that can be measured for a private firm (such as revenues, cash flow generating capacity, type of assets, variance in operating income) and are also available for publicly traded firms offers promise.

Aswath Damodaran

219

A Bid-Ask Spread Regression Using data from the end of 2000, for instance, we regressed the bid-ask spread against annual revenues, a dummy variable for positive earnings (DERN: 0 if negative and 1 if positive), cash as a percent of firm value and trading volume. Spread = 0.145 – 0.0022 ln (Annual Revenues) -0.015 (DERN) – 0.016 (Cash/Firm Value) – 0.11 ($ Monthly trading volume/ Firm Value)  You could plug in the values for a private firm into this regression (with zero trading volume) and estimate the spread for the firm.  We could substitute in the revenues of the Yankees ($209 million), the fact that it has positive earnings and the cash as a percent of revenues held by the firm (3%): Spread = 0.145 – 0.0022 ln (Annual Revenues) -0.015 (DERN) – 0.016 (Cash/Firm Value) – 0.11 ($ Monthly trading volume/ Firm Value) = 0.145 – 0.0022 ln (209) -0.015 (1) – 0.016 (.03) – 0.11 (0) = .1178 or 11.78%  Based on this approach, we would estimate an illiquidity discount of 11.78% for the Yankees. 

Aswath Damodaran

220

What is control worth?

The Value of Control X

Probability that you can change the management of the firm

Takeover Restrictions

Aswath Damodaran

Voting Rules & Rights

Access to Funds

Size of company

Change in firm value from changing management

Value of the firm run optimally

-

Value of the firm run status quo

221

Where control matters… 

In publicly traded firms, control is a factor • • •



In the pricing of every publicly traded firm, since a portion of every stock can be attributed to the market’s views about control. In acquisitions, it will determine how much you pay as a premium for a firm to control the way it is run. When shares have voting and non-voting shares, the value of control will determine the price difference.

In private firms, control usually becomes an issue when you consider how much to pay for a private firm. • • •

Aswath Damodaran

You may pay a premium for a badly managed private firm because you think you could run it better. The value of control is directly related to the discount you would attach to a minority holding (51%, but could be less…), you would be willing to pay the appropriate proportion of the optimal value of the firm. When you buy a minority interest in a firm, you will be willing to pay the appropriate fraction of the status quo value of the firm. For badly managed firms, there can be a significant difference in value between 51% of a firm and 49% of the same firm. This is the minority discount. If you own a private firm and you are trying to get a private equity or venture capital investor to invest in your firm, it may be in your best interests to offer them a share of control in the firm even though they may have well below 51%.

Aswath Damodaran

229

View more...

Comments

Copyright ©2017 KUPDF Inc.
SUPPORT KUPDF